The Parallel Universes of Institutional Investing and Institutional Voting
In a recent Corporate
Governance Commentary, titled “The Parallel Universes of
Institutional Investing and Institutional Voting, [1]”
we observed the increasing discontinuity at most institutional equity
investors between the persons who make the buy and sell decisions (or who
create and maintain the quantitative models that make those decisions) and
those who make the decisions on how to vote portfolio shares. We
analogized the separation of the two functions to parallel universes to
highlight the autonomous nature of each function. While we noted that this
pattern is not universal among institutional equity investors, we stated
our belief that it is the prevailing method by which institutional
investors solve the financial dilemma created by the large, and for some
institutions literally overwhelming, number of votes they are required to
cast each proxy season by the federal government’s imposition of a
fiduciary duty to vote all portfolio shares on all matters brought to
shareholders.
An obvious question is where
will the discontinuity of investment decision making and voting decision
making go from here? We believe there are three paradigms that describe
the most likely outcomes:
- Continuation and growth of
our current parallel universes paradigm, which consists of one
autonomous universe devoted to investment decisions and a second
autonomous universe devoted to voting decisions.
- Recognition that the
persons who make buy and sell decisions, institutional and retail, don’t
really care about voting their shares except on matters of clear
economic significance to them as owners of equity and that our current
structure of annual shareholder meetings and a plethora of shareholder
proposals is simply not interesting or relevant to the vast majority of
investment decision makers. A logical consequence would be to reduce the
frequency and number of non-economic votes throughout Corporate America
to better align the investment decision making reality and the voting
processes involved in corporate governance.
- Re-evaluation of the
application of fiduciary duty principles to the current parallel
universes, leading to modification or abandonment of the current
prevailing model of voting according to ex ante voting policies
without regard to the particular circumstances of the public company in
question.
This Corporate Governance
Commentary examines each of these paradigms in terms of its logic, its
implications for the future of corporate governance and its likelihood of
continuing as or becoming the dominant model.
First Paradigm:
Continuation of the Current Parallel Universes Model
There are a number of very
persuasive reasons for concluding that the current First Paradigm of
parallel universes will continue to prevail.
- As we noted in our
Parallel Universes Commentary, there are powerful economic motives for
institutional investors to utilize this model as the basis for voting
decisions. While some institutions may engage portfolio managers in
voting decisions to a greater extent than others, the economic value of
the paradigm rests on creation and implementation of one-size-fits-all
voting policies that permit the bulk of the voting decisions to be made
on the equivalent of “auto pilot.”
- The universe of voting
decision makers is dominated by the activist corporate governance
movement. Corporate governance activism has achieved widely accepted
legitimacy by its successful seizure of the rhetorical high ground,
based in large part on a number of simplistic but viscerally appealing
slogans, such as:
- Shareholders are the
“owners” of the company.
- The legitimacy of the
public company depends on “shareholder democracy,” expressed, among
other ways, through shareholder election of directors and shareholder
votes on other matters that shareholders believe important.
- Directors should be held
“accountable” to the company’s owners, among other ways, through
annual elections of the entire board, majority voting, proxy access,
the right to call special meetings and act by majority written
consent, elimination of all super majority voting requirements and
expansion of the right of shareholders to submit proposals for
consideration at shareholders’ meetings.
- The corporate governance
personnel within institutional money managers are “investors” or
“shareowners” for purposes of all corporate governance discussions and
the existence of the parallel universes can and should be ignored.
While critics have pointed
out on many occasions that these and other slogans of the corporate
governance parallel universe are insufficiently nuanced or tell only a
part of the story or are just wrong as a matter of theory and practice,
[2] their voices have been lost in the “proverbial”
wilderness.
This brings us to another,
perhaps the key, reason that the corporate governance parallel universe
has to date thoroughly won the thought leadership contest — its
slogan-oriented principles have been widely accepted and adopted by three
important constituencies:
- Labor, as purported
“investors” [3] (e.g., state and local
pension funds and unions), and also as self-appointed spokesman for
unionized and other employees who own stocks.
- The press.
- The political classes in
general, and most ardently the Democratic Party, at least on the
national level.
One can debate how much of
the corporate governance activists’ victory with these constituencies is
principles-based, how much of the corporate governance movement’s
influence with the financial press and politicians is a function of
Labor’s political (as opposed to its intellectual) clout, and how much of
the corporate governance activists’ intellectual victory is due to growth
of populist and progressive sentiments in our country over the past
several years. For our purposes, however, the relative share of credit or
blame is not nearly as important as the reality that all these underlying
currents are powerful and busily at work, and they will be hard to
reverse.
So there we have it. Absent
some rather dramatic change among the relevant constituencies, the
corporate governance parallel universe will not only continue into the
future, but as it achieves its agenda it will only get stronger and more
ambitious. The implications include:
- A good part of the
corporate governance agenda is explicitly aimed at making the board of
directors “accountable” to shareholders, not merely on an annual basis
but rather on a continuing year-round basis. The Dodd-Frank Act seals
victory for a portion of the current agenda of the corporate governance
community, principally proxy access and “say on pay.” The remaining
agenda includes legislatively mandating majority voting in uncontested
elections, permitting as few as 10 percent of the shareholders to call
special meetings, permitting action by majority shareholder consent
without a meeting throughout the year and eliminating all supermajority
voting provisions. A new concept that is receiving significant exposure
and could well become a corporate governance agenda item in the next
year or two borrows from Sweden a requirement that investor
representatives constitute some or all of the nominating committee for
directors. [4]
- “Accountability” in the
lexicon of the corporate governance universe more clearly than ever
means that directors should at all times act in accordance with the
wishes of the then prevailing majority of voting decision makers.
Failure to do so is seen as ample cause for not re-electing the
recalcitrant directors at the next annual meeting. [5]
- Real and increasing power
will flow to the corporate governance universe as its agenda of
corporate governance reforms is adopted by legislation, regulation or
corporate action at individual companies; success will breed further
success. Moreover, to maintain its importance and relevance, the
corporate governance universe will find it important to exercise its
increased power and to continue to develop a “reform” agenda that will
add to its power at the expense of the directors and management.
- Increased prescriptive
federal legislation and regulation is the best vehicle for rapid and
universal adoption of the future agenda of the corporate governance
universe.
- The leaders of the
corporate governance community undoubtedly understand that the numbers
of corporate governance specialists comprising their alternative
universe must remain limited to satisfy the economic motivations of
institutional investors to contain the costs of the parallel voting
universe. As a result, the sheer number of public companies is a real
life problem for the corporate governance community in achieving its
existing and future “reform” agenda. With over 10,000 in the US and
the enabling premise of state corporation laws, the actual governance
schemes of the public company universe are kaleidoscopic.
- The variation in
corporate governance details among US public companies presents a
severe challenge if the corporate governance universe is forced to act
on a case by case basis through a shareholder vote or a believable
threat of a shareholder vote at each public company. The obvious
solution is to eliminate the need for company-by-company campaigns
through adoption of one-size-fits-all prescriptive laws and
regulation. This is the principal argument made by the corporate
governance community in its lobbying campaign at the SEC against
permitting meaningful shareholder choice under the SEC’s proxy access
rules. [6] It is also a major argument used by the
corporate governance community in lobbying Congress for adoption of
prescriptive corporate governance legislation in the pending financial
services legislation. This argument will be heard and, based on the
precedent in the proxy access debate, frequently responded to by the
SEC and quite possibly Congress. The result could well be further
inroads in our once almost sacrosanct division between state and
federal authority in the regulation of the internal affairs of public
companies.
- Indeed, it is not wholly
far-fetched to predict that the corporate governance universe may
begin sponsoring a full federalization of corporate law under a
prescriptive statutory scheme. Were this to occur, it is not difficult
to predict that the prescriptive federal statute would “level” all of
the structural devices that are perceived to reduce the accountability
of all directors to shareholders at large. [7]
Left to run its course, the
parallel universe of corporate governance will increase its domination
over the board room and executive suite. While there will be differences
among the one-size-fits-all voting policies at different institutions and
third party proxy advisors, they will be at the margin. The central core
voting policies will continue to be determined by a relatively small
coterie of corporate governance leaders, without meaningful input from
persons with alternative views of shareholder, board and executive officer
dynamics and functions.
Second Paradigm:
Recognition of Investing Decision Makers’ Lack of Interest in Shareholder
Voting
It should not come as a shock
to anyone involved in equity investing or corporate governance that, on
the whole, persons who participate in portfolio management, those who make
the buy sell decisions or create and manage the programs that make the buy
and sell decisions, have little to no interest in voting portfolio shares,
except in cases of clear economic significance (principally mergers,
fundamental corporate restructurings and control contests). This is also
true of retail investors, whatever their investment style. For portfolio
managers, active or quantitative, institutional or retail,
[8] the only corporate governance (as opposed to economic) vote that
counts is the buy or sell decision. If an active manager of a portfolio
likes a company’s performance and it fits his portfolio’s objectives it’s
a buy or hold. If the performance is disappointing or worse it’s a sale.
The quantitative manager is even further removed from voting because its
investment thesis is based on quantitative models that operate on the
basis of their internal logic. Voting shares is not just an afterthought
for the quantitative manager, it is simply irrelevant. [9]
The reality of investment
decision makers’ apathy with regard to exercise of the corporate franchise
on votes without obvious economic significance raises a truly fundamental
question. Why do we have, and do we need, so many shareholder votes?
- Shareholder democracy is
not an answer. Democracy does not demand annual elections for the
governing body. Indeed, it would be hard to find any federal or state
legislator in the US who would espouse the wisdom of an annual election
cycle. Nor does shareholder democracy demand that there be a corporate
analog to the California voter initiative system in the form of
shareholder proposals, binding and non-binding. [10]
Add to the mix an ability for shareholders to meet between annual
meetings at the behest of as few as 10 percent of the shareholders or to
act by majority written consent at any time, coupled with a right to
remove directors without cause (all key items on the corporate
governance movement’s current agenda and a reality at a meaningful
number of public companies). While the result is like an Athenian style
democracy, it is hardly the only democratic model available.
- One consequence of the
corporate governance universe’s drive toward total director and
management “accountability” on an annual or more frequent basis is its
implicit rejection of a long time horizon for corporate strategy and
investment. Commentators across the spectrum of corporate governance
issues often decry the quarterly growth ethos that seems to dominate
management, board and investment decision makers thinking and action.
[11] The inexorable pressure of producing
quarter-over-quarter growth is frequently blamed for the excesses and
mistakes of Corporate America, whether it be the financial institutions
of the second half of this decade or the telecoms and other high-flyers
of the first half. A particular irony is that the corporate governance
universe often boasts of its pre-eminence at the table of long term
investors because its predominant investment style is indexing, not
stock picking, and thus, by hypothesis, its investment arms own
indefinitely the stocks that make up their target index. Yet, very often
it is the very same long term index “investors” who are driving the
corporate governance universe’s campaign to create an Athenian style
corporate democracy, which practically insures short term thinking by
boards and management.
Shareholder democracy can
easily take forms other than an Athenian democracy model. We have only to
look at our national legislature to find a very different democratic
model.
- US senators serve
staggered six year terms, with elections of one-third only every other
year. US representatives serve two year terms. On a national level,
there is no annual election cycle. Moreover, the framers of our
Constitution clearly saw considerable merit in having the senior
representative body elected for longer, staggered terms, to promote
stability, longer term thinking and some measure of insulation from the
vagaries of public opinion on an annual or even biennial basis. Applying
these principles to boards of directors would be fully consistent with
shareholder democracy and would avoid the obvious economic and policy
pitfalls of an annual or more frequent election cycle.
- Objectors to lengthening
the term of directors and revitalizing staggered boards might reject the
analogy to the Congressional pattern, arguing that directors, unlike
Senators and Representatives, rarely run against opposition, thus making
the nature of the election different. However, this difference is
narrowing rapidly under the pressure from the corporate governance
universe’s agenda. Proxy access will undoubtedly lead to a larger number
of contested elections. Moreover, withhold-vote campaigns are
increasingly frequent and successful, and the possible advent of
universally required majority voting will vastly increase the threat of
withhold-vote and vote “no” campaigns. Finally, whether or not proxy
access nominations and withhold-vote campaigns are actually used by
unhappy members of the corporate governance universe at many companies,
the threat of use is ever present.
The basic point of this
analysis is that one obvious, if seemingly radical, way to deal with the
reality that investment decision makers simply don’t care about most
shareholder votes would be to reduce the number and subject matter of
shareholder votes. For example:
- We could abandon the
annual meeting for a biennial meeting. As suggested above, directors
could be elected for longer terms and boards could be staggered.
Literally adopting the election scheme of the US Senate would provide a
far longer time horizon for directors and management, while preserving
the ability of shareholders to reshape the board over time.
- Special meetings called by
management to consider transformational changes would remain unaffected
by the reforms in director elections, in recognition of the fact that
these events are not only appropriate for shareholder voting but also
ones for which investment decision makers want a voice.
- We could also eliminate
the ability of shareholders to submit non-binding, precatory proposals
at shareholder meetings. [12] In lieu of non-binding
shareholder resolutions, we could empower shareholders to make
suggestions for change in corporate governance or company policy by
facilitating electronic shareholder bulletin boards, straw polls or the
like. The rapidly evolving world of social networking is readily
available and contains a number of models that could be utilized for
effective shareholder communications with the board and management.
- We could deal with
concerns about director entrenchment by limiting the duration of poison
pills, for instance, to one year. We could also create a fail-safe
mechanism for director removal in extreme cases through a right of a
meaningful minority of shareholders (say 25-35 percent) to convene a
special shareholders’ meeting solely for that purpose.
In sum, there is nothing
sacrosanct about our current shareholder voting system. It can be altered
in many ways to achieve the goal of lessening the short-termism inherent
in an Athenian democratic model, while preserving the rights of
shareholders to elect directors periodically, vote on economically
significant transactions and communicate more effectively and with less
risk to the enterprise’s stability.
On the other hand, there is
no denying that a reform of our current shareholder voting system, or even
a proposal for reform, will be seen by the corporate governance universe,
and many others, as radical, counter-productive, undemocratic and worse.
Academics and others will argue passionately that it doesn’t merely ignore
the agency costs that are rife in Corporate America, it exacerbates them.
It will be characterized as a clumsy, but revealing, defense of the status
quo and the underserved prerogatives of boards and management. Recounting
of recent and not so recent tales of board and management errors and
misdeeds will be recited with glee. And so forth and so on.
If a debate results it will
probably be for the good. At least it will help illuminate the “dirty
little” secret that lies at the heart of our current system of corporate
governance — that investment decision makers are not on the whole very
interested in corporate governance as it is currently practiced, or at
least in the voting opportunities increasingly demanded by the prevailing
corporate governance agenda.
Third Paradigm:
Reevaluation of Institutional Investors’ Fiduciary Duty to Vote All
Portfolio Shares
As noted in our Parallel
Universes Commentary, the parallel investing and voting universes were
effectively created in the 1980’s and 1990’s when federal agencies imposed
on US institutional investors a fiduciary duty to vote all portfolio
shares on all ballot matters. The cost and challenge of doing so have been
met by the creation of the parallel corporate governance universe armed
with detailed ex ante voting policies which are applied
predominantly on a one-size-fits-all basis across the panoply of US public
companies.
The effectiveness of this
model rests on the assumption that voting decisions can be delegated to
specialists and third party proxy advisors so as to fulfill the
institution’s fiduciary duties without imposing undue costs on the
institution. It is not clear, however, that the parallel voting universe
that has evolved over the past 25 years successfully discharges
institutional investors’ fiduciary duties of due care and loyalty.
Let us first examine the duty
of care. It is commonly articulated in terms of a prudent man standard.
That is, the obligation to vote portfolio shares must be discharged with
the same degree of care that would be used by a prudent investor under
like circumstances. [13] The question is whether the
alternative voting universe meets that standard. A number of
considerations suggest that it may not.
- A critical underlying
premise of the parallel voting universe is that there is a body of good
governance principles and best practices which, if implemented at a
public company, will create shareholder value. Indeed, this is the
bedrock assumption that supports the edifice of the voting universe.
However, at best there is a lack consensus among scholars whether this
is empirically true. And many academic critics would go further and
assert there is no persuasive empirical evidence that good corporate
governance, as defined in the parallel voting universe, has a meaningful
impact on corporate performance or the creation of positive value for
shareholders. [14]
- A second cause for concern
is that much of what is proclaimed to be good corporate governance lacks
a strong theoretical foundation and seems to be a product of a mindset
more than a discipline. For example, a unifying theme of the corporate
governance universe is that directors must be “accountable” to
shareholders who are the true “owners” of the business. As noted above,
this sentiment may be appealing rhetorically, but accountability is not
self-defining and may be interpreted and applied in a number of ways.
Moreover, the corporate governance universe has not clearly defined how
its concept of accountability fits into a more comprehensive model of
corporate governance? How does it relate to other corporate governance
issues, such as the role and responsibilities of a board with regard to
the company’s management and its business and finances? Should a board’s
first priority be monitoring management and, if so, on what bases and to
what end; or should a board’s priority be to actively counsel management
on strategic planning and implementation? Moreover, what is the basis
for assuming that there is but one answer to these and other structural
questions about a board’s role and responsibilities? Why should the
governance model be the same for all public companies? In short,
accountability sounds good as an aspiration, but it is nothing more than
a slogan unless and until it is defined precisely and fit into the far
broader context of a comprehensive corporate governance model for
managing the broad array of public companies and for creating
shareholder value.
- A closely related issue is
the circular and self-validating nature of the generation and
confirmation of governance best practices within the corporate
governance universe. A frequent pattern is for a corporate governance
reform to be surfaced by one or several thought leaders within the
universe as an appealing idea, for other members of the universe to
endorse the idea, for RiskMetrics to propose incorporating the idea into
its voting policies and for the very same thought leaders who sponsored
the idea to confirm their support of RiskMetrics’ adoption of the
standard as part of its voting policies. When the circle ends, the
proposed best practice is viewed as validated by members of the voting
universe (who are referred to as “investors” for purposes of further
validation) and incorporated in RiskMetric’s and other institutional
investor voting policies on the basis of its wide-spread acceptance
within the parallel voting universe. Notably, empirical evidence of
suitability and value creation for the broad swath of US public
companies is at best scanty and often simply not part of the process.
- Another conceptual problem
with the corporate governance model that has been developed and
implemented by the parallel voting universe is its core
one-size-fits-all structure. Indeed, as noted above, the model has to be
largely automated to create the economies of scale on which the universe
depends for cost containment. Having to apply corporate governance
principles on a case-by-case basis in the context of the facts and
circumstances of over 10,000 public companies would undermine the
economic utility of the separate voting universe.
- A final fundamental
problem inherent in the parallel corporate governance universe and its
voting policies model is that members of that universe do not have any
responsibility or accountability for the economic performance of their
institution’s stock portfolio. The lack of accountability and
responsibility is even more obvious at the proxy advisory firms. By
hypothesis, the parallel corporate governance universe is simply not
about portfolio performance. While governance professionals frequently
assert that good corporate governance leads to good corporate
performance, to date this remains a matter of belief for which there is
at best only equivocal empirical support. At the end of the day, the
fact that corporate governance exists in a parallel universe, which is
essentially separate from the universe of investment decision making is
the strongest indictment of the paradigm and one that should give great
pause to a prudent investment decision maker.
The duty of care issue boils
down to whether a truly prudent investor — one who makes buy and sell
decisions — would and should be comfortable using the model that the
parallel corporate governance universe has created. The model may be
expedient; it may contain costs and make the voting process economically
sustainable for the institutional investor. But in what sense is it an
expression of how a prudent investment decision maker, one who is
responsible and accountable for the economic performance of a portfolio,
would vote his or her portfolio shares?
The foregoing discussion also
highlights the challenge in fitting the alternative universe’s corporate
governance model into a duty of loyalty analysis. One of the bedrock
principles of the duty of loyalty is that the fiduciary should act solely
for the benefit of the beneficiary, not for the fiduciary’s economic
self-interest. [15] Yet the latter motive, not the
former, is the informing principle for use of ex ante voting policies
intended to be broadly applicable to all public companies, without regard
to the wide variation in facts and circumstances among more than 10,000
public companies. To defend the corporate governance parallel universe in
the context of the duty of loyalty seemingly requires total acceptance of
the basic premise that voting policies developed by the members of the
parallel voting universe are universally applicable to all public
companies and do, in fact, generate value for each separately managed
equity portfolio, even if the value creation is not subject to empirical
proof.
At the end of the day it is
for courts to decide the question whether the parallel corporate
governance universe fulfills the fiduciary duties of investment managers.
There is, however, a third
paradgm that would be far easier to defend under a fiduciary duty analysis
and that would answer most of the criticisms of the prevailing parallel
universes paradigm. The third paradigm would concede that variations in
company circumstances can impact the suitability and desirability of
applying particular corporate governance policies to that company.
Accordingly, it would require an informed inquiry into those circumstances
and an analysis of the pros and cons of application of a specific
governance policy to a particular company at a particular time.
Corporate governance
professionals are not suited to a company specific analysis. By
hypothesis, they are not investment professionals. But active investment
decision makers are. They and their staffs meet company managements,
attend quarterly earnings calls, road shows and management presentations,
and typically care about the quality and foibles of each portfolio
company’s management. They will often have a sense of whether a particular
governance reform makes sense in the context of the companies they follow.
In the third paradigm, the
existing corporate governance model of virtually rote voting in accordance
with ex ante voting policies would be modified by requiring input
and final decisions on voting by investment professionals, not governance
professionals. This paradigm, to continue the analogy, would tilt the
existing parallel universes’ axes so that the two universes intersect and
overlap to a meaningful degree. Rather than voting decisions defaulting to
corporate governance specialists unless an investment decision maker
mustered a persuasive case for a different outcome, the default would be
to the investment decision maker unless a corporate governance
professional mustered a persuasive case for a different outcome.
By reuniting the investing
and voting functions and according final decision making to investment
professional based on the specifics of each company, the third paradigm
would successfully resolve many of the more troublesome weaknesses of the
parallel universes paradigm:
- It would create economic
accountability and responsibility for voting decisions by requiring
votes to be cast by investment managers actually responsible for
investment performance, not by parties with no economic “skin in the
game”.
- It would eliminate the
one-size-fits-all application of voting policies in favor of more
specific company-based voting decisions.
- It would require corporate
governance specialists to make the case for application of an ex
ante voting policy to a specific company, thereby eliminating some
of most insidious aspects of the current paradigm’s closed circle of
creation and validation.
The third paradigm certainly
raises a number of practical issues. Not the least is that it would impose
more cost on institutional investors than the current parallel universes
model. However, that cost is part and parcel of the fiduciary duty imposed
on institutional investors by the federal government. The solution to the
cost issue should not be to minimize costs for investment managers at the
expense of prudent investment decision making. If the cost of requiring
that voting decisions be company specific outweighs the benefit of
requiring institutional investors to vote all portfolio shares on all
matters, the logical answer is to eliminate the requirement to vote all
portfolio shares on all matters.
Opponents of the proposed
third paradigm could also argue that requiring greater participation by
investment decision makers in the voting process is all fine and good for
active money managers. But it makes no sense for quantitative investors,
which like the governance specialists, have no company specific knowledge
to apply to the voting decision.
This is where proxy advisory
firms could supply a truly useful function, beyond being a cog in the
circular process of validation of corporate governance ideas and a cheaper
provider of the application of one-size-fits-all voting policies to the
tens of thousands of proxy votes needed each proxy season. Proxy advisory
firms could establish an infrastructure composed of investment decision
making professionals which would be tasked with developing sufficient
company specific knowledge to make informed voting decisions for all
quantitative investors.
- True, such an expanded
infrastructure would be far more costly than the current proxy advisory
firm model. But this cost would be shared among all quantitative
investment advisers. Doing so would add cost to the quantitative
investment model, but again that cost is inherent in the fiduciary duty
to vote all portfolio shares imposed on all investment managers.
- For active managers, the
cost of the third paradigm would be the time required to be spent by
portfolio managers in taking responsibility for voting decisions. For
quantitative managers, the cost would be the institution’s share of the
“utility services” provided by proxy advisory firms which would be
required to utilize investment professionals to analyze voting
recommendations on a case-by-case basis.
Conclusion
To recap, there are three
basic paradigms for the future of share voting decisions by institutional
investors in the US.
- Continuation and growth of
the current parallel universes of investment and voting decision making.
- Abandonment of the current
model of annual shareholder meetings (replete with election of directors
increasingly for one year terms and often contentious shareholder
proposals) in favor of fewer meetings, longer terms for directors and
curtailment or abandonment of the SEC created shareholder proposal
system.
- Elimination of the
parallel universes in favor of a more integrated voting model that takes
into account differences in company circumstances and requires
investment decision makers to have a far greater role in the voting
process than the currently prevailing model.
Of these paradigms, the last
seems to us by far the best. It is not without its conceptual and
practical issues and certainly not without its costs. However, by
reuniting the investing function and the voting function, it far better
serves the fiduciary duty requirements of federal law and resolves the
most glaring weakness of our current share voting system which is
dominated by a parallel corporate governance universe that is without
responsibility or accountability for the effect of those votes on
particular companies and those companies’ ability to generate shareholder
value.
Endnotes
[1]
http://www.lw.com/upload/pubContent/_pdf/pub3463_1.pdf (the “Parallel
Universes Commentary”).
[2]
Martin Lipton & William Savitt, The Many Myths of Lucian Bebchuk,
93 Va. L. Rev. 733 (2007); Martin Lipton & Steven A. Resenblum,
Election Contests in the Company’s Proxy: An Idea Whose Time Has Not Come,
59 BUS. LAW 67, 69 (2003); Martin Lipton & Paul K. Rowe, The
Inconvenient Truth About Corporate Governance: Some Thoughts on
Vice-Chancellor Strine’s Essay, 33 J. Corp. L. 63 (2007); ABA Section
of Business Law, Report of The Task Force of the ABA Section of
Business Law Corporate Governance Committee on Delineation Of Governance
Roles &Responsibilities (2009),
http://www.abanet.org/buslaw/committees/CL260000pub/materials/20090801/delineation-final.pdf.
[3]
State and local employee pension plans and national and local labor unions
control the assets in their various pension funds, but they routinely hire
third-party investment managers to actually make the investment decisions.
Thus, like the corporate governance specialists who control institutional
investors’ voting, they are “investors” in name only.
[4]
Corporate governance activists frequently argue that these reforms are
intended for use only in extraordinary situations. This argument ignores
the leverage created by the ability of corporate governance activists to
threaten a company with their use if the company resists demanded
“reforms” being advanced by the corporate governance universe.
[5]
RiskMetrics, for example, has long maintained a voting policy of
recommending that shareholders withhold voting for an entire board of a
company if the board has not implemented to RiskMetrics’ satisfaction a
shareholder proposal that has carried a majority of the votes cast at two
successive annual meeting or a majority of the outstanding shares at a
single annual meeting. RiskMetrics justifies this policy by the need for a
board to be accountable to shareholders. The RiskMetrics policy has had
great success in motivating boards to implement shareholder proposals that
have carried a majority vote or are perceived likely to do so.
[6]
E.g., CII, Comment Letter to the SEC Concerning Proposed Rule
Facilitating Shareholder Director Nominations, File No. S7-10-09 (Jan. 14.
2010),
http://www.sec.gov/comments/s7-10-09/s71009-592.pdf; CalSTRS, Comment
Letter to the SEC Concerning Proposed Rule Facilitating Shareholder
Director Nominations, File No. S7-10-09 (Nov. 18, 2009),
http://www.sec.gov/comments/s7-10-09/s71009-573.pdf; TIAA-CREF,
Comment Letter to the SEC Concerning Proposed Rule Facilitating
Shareholder Director Nominations, File No. S7-10-09 (Sept. 18, 2009),
http://www.sec.gov/comments/s7-10-09/s71009-536.pdf.
[7]
This would probably include permitting only one class of common stock with
equal voting rights, limiting the ability of preferred classes to
participate in corporate governance to avoid undermining the hegemony of
the mandatory one vote per share common stock, prescribing that all
directors may be removed without cause, eliminating all forms of
classified boards (including two classes of stock, each with the right to
elect a specified number of directors), mandating investor participation
at the nominating committee, and so on and so forth.
[8]
The SEC has recently added senior staff in its Office of Investor
Education and Advocacy and created a web site devoted to educating retail
investors and encouraging them to vote their shares,
http://www.sec.gov/investor/pubs/sec-guide-to-proxy-brochures.pdf.
Whether this effort will change the current sorry demographics of retail
voting remains to be seen. What is clear is that retail investors
historically have not had a high voting rate and consciously or otherwise
relied on broker discretionary voting to be heard at the corporate polls.
With the practical demise of broker discretionary voting, the retail
investing community has become relatively insignificant in share voting on
non-economic matters.
[9]
The principal exception to these generalizations about investor
disinterest in voting are hedge funds and other activist managers that
follow a so-called “event driven” investment style. For these investors,
the Icahns and Ackmans of the world, voting is inextricably part of their
investing style. In many ways, they are the inheritors of the classic
shareholders of the early days of the American corporation, when
shareholders were “owners” in a very direct way and there was little or no
intermediation between the capitalists who made investments of their
personal funds and the men who ran their companies.
[10]
Indeed, the corporate analog is arguably more insidious because under Rule
14a-8 virtually any shareholder can get a proposal onto the ballot.
[11]
Martin Lipton & William Savitt, The Many Myths of Lucian Bebchuk,
93 VA. L. REV. 733 (2007); Martin Lipton & Steven A. Resenblum,
Election Contests in the Company’s Proxy: An Idea Whose Time Has Not Come,
59 BUS. LAW. 67, 69 (2003); Leo E. Strine, Jr., Toward Common Sense
and Common Ground? Reflections on the Shared Interests of Managers and
Labor in a More Rational System of Corporate Governance, 33 J. CORP.
L. 1, 16 (2007); Leo R. Strine, Jr., Keynote Address at the University of
Iowa Journal of Corporation Law Symposium (2007); CalPERS, Global
Principles of Accountable Corporate Governance (2010),
http://www.calpers-governance.org/docs-sof/principles/2010-5-2-global-principles-of-accountable-corp-gov.pdf;
CalSTRS, CalSTRS Executive Compensation Model Policy Guidelines
(2009),
http://www.calstrs.com/investments/ExecutiveCompensationGuidelines.pdf.
[12]
As Vice Chancellor Strine frequently notes, the non-binding shareholder
resolution is largely the product of Rule 14a-8 and has no basis or analog
in state corporation law. Leo E. Strine, Jr., Vice Chancellor, Del. Court
of Chancery, SEC Roundtable Discussion on Proposals for Shareholders (May
25, 2007) (transcript available at
http://www.sec.gov/news/openmeetings/2007/openmtg_trans052507.pdf).
[13]
See Letter from U.S. Dep’t of Labor to Helmuth Fandl, Chairman of
Retirement Board, Avon Products, Inc. (Feb. 23, 1988); see also
73 Fed. Reg. 61731 (Oct. 17, 2008) (requiring “monitoring of corporate
management of plan fiduciaries” under ERISA). For a recent restatement of
this policy, see Proxy Voting by Investment Advisors, 68 Fed. Reg. 6585
(Feb. 7, 2003) (“The duty of care requires an adviser with proxy voting
authority to monitor corporate events and to vote the proxies. To satisfy
its duty of loyalty, the adviser must cast the proxy votes in a manner
consistent with the best interest of its client and must not subrogate
client interests to its own” (internal citations omitted)).
[14]
See Sanjai Bhagat et al., The Promise and Peril of Corporate
Governance Indices, 108 COLUM. L. REV. 1803 (2008) (arguing that
there is no consistent relation between particular governance measures and
corporate performance); see also Daines et al., Rating the
Ratings: How Good are Commercial Governance Ratings, Working Paper,
September 4, 2009, available at
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1152093; see also Richard Leblanc &
James Gillies, Inside the Boardroom: How Boards Really Work and the Coming
Revolution in Corporate Governance, pp. 62-63, 80, 107-108, 120-126
(2005); id. at p. 125 (“where independent governance [is] clearly
of superior benefit to shareholders, we would expect to see the results
reflected in the results of scholarly research. Such results, however, are
not evident. Other studies of the relationship between board size and firm
performance provide no consensus about the direction of the relationship
and suggest there is no statistical evidence of a relationship between
corporate performance and proportion of outside directors of a board” (internal
citations omitted); id. at p. 125 (“for every company that
one can quote as an example demonstrating a positive correlation between
good corporate governance, as defined by board structure, and good
corporate financial performance, another that followed very good corporate
governance practices can be found with a negative relationship”); Jeffrey
Sonnenfeld, Good Governance and the Misleading Myths of Bad Metrics,
available at
http://www.sec.gov/spotlight/dir-nominations/sonnenfeld012004.pdf (“we
are finding no support for a relationship between structural dimensions of
board governance and company performance”).
[15]
The duty of loyalty does not allow a director or officer to consider or
represent interests other than the best interests of the corporation and
its stockholders in making a business decision. Belotti R. Franklin,
Delaware Law of Corporations and Business Organizations 4-117 (2010)
(citing Andarko Petroleum Corp. v. Panhandle E. Corp., 545 A.2d
1171, 1174 (Del. 1998)). The Model Business Corporation Act states that a
fiduciary has a duty to act “in a manner the officer believes is in the
best interest of the corporation” and when a fiduciary or a related person
enters into a transaction with a material financial interest opposite of
the corporation’s interest, the fiduciary may be in breach of his duties.
MBCA §§ 8.30, 8.42, 8.60 (4th ed. 2008).
© 2010 The
President and Fellows of Harvard College |
|