Speech
Opening Remarks to
SEC-NYU
Dialogue on Securities
Markets #4:
Shareholder Engagement
Jay Clayton
Chairman
New York, N.Y.
Jan.
19, 2018
Good morning, and thank you, Dean Morrison, for that kind
introduction. It is a pleasure to be back at NYU and to be in the
company of so many who care deeply about our markets and our
investors.
Special thanks also goes to Alexander Ljungqvist, Anthony Lynch, Ed
Rock, and others from the Salomon Center for the Study of Financial
Institutions and the Stern School of Business at New York University.
Thank you also to the staff in the Division of Economic and Risk
Analysis, for all of the preparation required to make an event like
this happen.
This is now the fourth in the series of SEC-NYU dialogues, and I am
pleased with the four topics that have been covered, as well as the
quality of the discussions thus far. It is important that the SEC be
able to take a forward-looking approach with respect to our securities
markets — to keep up to date with key developments, and be alert to
issues where regulation may be appropriate in the future. Hearing
about new developments or theories — whether they require us to take
specific action or not — is an important part of that process. At the
end of the day, our ability to spot growing issues and head them off
with thoughtful, informed, incremental regulation, or deregulation,
will always be preferable to addressing problems retrospectively,
including through enforcement.
I also appreciate these SEC-NYU dialogues for their cross-disciplinary
focus. Bringing together practitioners, stakeholders, regulators, and
academics of various stripes to exchange ideas means that our views
can be subject to debate and analysis by those with a perspective
different from our own. Iron sharpens iron; we are all the better for
it.
Today’s SEC-NYU dialogue will focus on the current state of
shareholder engagement, including the roles of institutional and
activist investors — and how those roles have changed over time. I’ll
try to set the table.
The governance structure of public companies reflects the reality of
capital allocation in a well-functioning free market economy: capital
is allocated predominantly on a collective but widely distributed
basis; in practice, companies have many shareholders who have no
connection to one another. Various factors drive this approach to
collective capital allocation, including that, first, in a global
economy, firms have necessarily become large (and therefore very few
can be funded by a single investor or small group of investors).
Second, from an investor’s perspective, diversification across
investment opportunities has proven to be a prudent and attractive
strategy. As a result, firm ownership is diffused and ever-changing.
This is fertile ground for the age old problems of collective action.
How do we address collective action problems? There are several
proven approaches but, for companies, we have long settled on the
approach of selecting dedicated individuals to oversee the company’s
affairs and imposing on them a fiduciary duty. These fiduciaries
generally own no more than a small portion of the company.
While the U.S. approach to capital allocation and firm governance is a
proven approach — and I firmly believe the best approach — it is not a
perfect one. The separation of ownership and control raises alignment
of interests questions — or as my fellow economists say (I’m upgrading
my status here), principal-agent problems. How can the principals
(the stockholders) be sure their agents (the managers) are acting in
the best interests of the stockholders? These are not new issues. I
studied them in earnest 30 years ago and my professors at the time had
been studying them for 30 years before that. We have, however, in
practice made significant strides in the past 30 years. These strides
have been driven by many factors, including our experiences — both
good and (unfortunately) bad — new or changing regulation, and,
importantly, as a result of substantial reductions in the costs of
monitoring and shareholder communications. The information
asymmetries and absences that plague principal-agent relationships
have been narrowed. As regulators, we have mandated or suggested rule
sets — including disclosure requirements and incentive driving
requirements and prohibitions — that have reduced the opportunities
for misalignment between shareholders and managers. Based on my
observations and, more significantly, my interactions with various
market participants, I believe it is clear that governance has
improved as a result.
Our work is far from over. Why? Not because more rules are better,
but because our work has not been perfect, and because markets are
ever-changing. We need to ask if our rule set has kept pace. For
example, increasingly, a second layer of separation between ownership
and control has opened between the ultimate owners of capital and
corporate management. Shareholders invest in investment vehicles —
mutual funds, ETFs, etc. — which in turn own the shares of operating
companies. In theory, a daisy chain of fiduciary duties keeps these
interactions focused on the interests of the ultimate beneficial
owner, but it also means that the principal-agent issues are
multi-layered.
In addition to principal-agent alignment issues, there also are
shareholder alignment issues within the body of shareholders of the
same firm. The key issue to understand how best to serve the
interests of the ultimate owners of capital is to understand what they
want. This issue, while facially straightforward, also is vexing —
particularly when you dip below the level of broad principles.
Shareholders often have different and sometimes divergent views on
objectives and how best to achieve the selected objectives. This is
not a surprise. Shareholders can have vastly different investment
time horizons. As a well-known specific example, we have seen many
cases where some shareholders believe capital should be reinvested
while others believe it should be returned to shareholders through buy
backs or dividends.
To take a slightly more complex example, let’s assume an index fund
that owns, as a part of that index, a company that may be poorly
managed. What might an investor in that index fund expect the fund’s
investment manager to do? Perhaps the fund should do absolutely
nothing: investors may simply want the lowest-cost exposure to the
market, warts and all. Perhaps the fund should do nothing
affirmative, but if an activist engages with the mismanaged company,
the fund could support the activist — which would ideally drive up the
stock price with the index fund along for the ride. Perhaps the fund
should intervene directly — if the index fund can’t exit the
investment, then being an activist passive fund may be the best path
toward increasing the value of the fund. How should an index fund
select from among these options? Should index funds seek guidance
from investors in the fund, or clearly disclose their engagement
policies such that potential investors could self-select into their
desired category?
And what if the company is not being actively mismanaged, but simply
lacks some of the governance features that governance professionals
have deemed to be “best practice”? Should the passive index fund
actively pre-empt? Should the index criteria themselves take on this
issue? Recently, particularly at larger public companies, active
shareholders have sought to establish or modify specific aspects of
governance rule sets, as well as company policies on an array of
environmental and social topics. How should companies respond to
those overtures? How should other investment funds react?
These are all complicated issues, with no easy answers, in large part
because engagement, while it is valuable in many cases, is not free.
It costs shareholders time and money to engage and, for some
shareholders — or in some cases, a substantial majority of
shareholders — the marginal benefit of engaging on a particular topic
may not be worth the effort. Let’s not forget that the
director-officer fiduciary duty model itself was designed to, and does
effectively, if not perfectly, address the fundamental problem of fair
and efficient collective action.
One more point on structure. Even proxy voting is costly to
shareholders: analyzing the issue up for a vote, the potentially
varying points of view on that issue, formulating an opinion, and
casting the ballot is a series of actions that requires nuanced
determinations that may be beyond individual shareholders. Even
investment companies struggle. Because they frequently compete on
fees, are funds tempted to understaff proxy voting, or to outsource it
to a proxy advisory firm? Have we added a third layer of
principal-agent issues? Has it helped?
These are all questions that we need to be examining, and I hope
today’s discussion can shed some light on at least some of them.
Turning from structure to market realities of the day: Few companies
are immune to activist pressures — as two of our distinguished
panelists here today will no doubt discuss, activist owners can
substantively influence the governance of the largest of companies.
And, increasingly, they are doing so. Activism may be evolving, but
it is not going away. So it is more important than ever for
shareholders to understand and evaluate activists’ long-term impact on
companies and shareholder value. In particular, to what extent do
shareholder campaigns launched by activist investors create value for
all shareholders? What is the effect of these campaigns on long-term
value? To what extent does passive institutional ownership – and the
involvement of proxy advisors – facilitate the growth in activist
campaigns? And activists themselves are not monolithic; they may
themselves have different tactics or different time horizons that may
lead to differential outcomes with respect to this range of
questions. Do activists take advantage of the imperfections in our
system or do they smooth them? I’ll give an answer — it’s probably
both.
As we explore these issues, I want us to keep in mind a group of
shareholders whose voices rarely have a place at the table: the Main
Street Investor. The engine of economic growth in this country
depends significantly on the willingness of Main Street investors to
put their hard-earned capital at risk in our markets over the long
term. If our system of corporate governance is not ensuring that the
views and fundamental interests of these long-term retail investors
are being protected, then we have a lot of work to do to make it so.
I look forward to hearing the discussions, analyses, and
recommendations that will come out of today’s event. Thank you all
for agreeing to spend your time with us so that we can benefit from
your insights. I wish you a day full of enjoyable and fruitful
discussions. |