Expert views of proposed SEC revisions of 13D stock ownership
reporting requirements
For a copy of the author's referenced
letter to the Securities and Exchange Commission,
click here.
Note: Jeffrey
Gordon, the author of the article below, has provided guidance as
well as
Columbia's co-hosting of public Forum programs
that defined investor interests in both marketplace practices and
regulatory policies.
Last February, the Securities and Exchange Commission proposed to
“modernize” the reporting of beneficial ownership of a company’s stock
under section 13(d) of the 1934 Securities Exchange Act. As I
explained in a recent comment letter to the SEC, the proposal is
flawed in several ways. First, it risks suppressing proxy contests,
which are the principal, if not the sole, method for holding corporate
managers accountable to shareholders. Second, to the degree the
Commission is concerned about improper tipping of information related
to activist engagements, that concern can and should be addressed by
developing new rules specific to such tipping and trading rather than
by the proposal’s ambiguous new definition of a “group.” Third, in
light of the SEC’s concerns about the use of swaps to disguise
potential control positions, I propose a “safe harbor” for parties
entering into certain swaps that clearly do not implicate those
concerns. Finally, the Commission’s proposed definition of “group” is
theoretically untenable and practically unworkable and should be
abandoned until the SEC can more carefully consider its implications.
The proposal’s biggest flaw is, perhaps, its likely threat to proxy
contests. First, a framing point. The Williams Act was enacted in
1968 to deal with the surge of a new form of control transaction, the
hostile tender offer, which could result in a transfer of control
through the accumulation of shares in a very short period. The act
had two elements: first, the creation of an “early warning system”
under section 13(d) to alert the target and investors of an
accumulation of stock that could precede a control transaction, and
second, the regulation of the tender offer itself under section
14(d). Hostile tender offers, however, are essentially a thing of
the past, suppressed by the poison pill, a private-ordering creation
licensed by state corporate law. It would be perverse to the turn
section 13(d) of the Williams Act against what was the preferred form
of governance challenge prior to the hostile tender offer – the proxy
contest – but this is what the SEC’s proposal risks doing. This point
must be emphasized: Without a credible threat of maintaining a proxy
contest an activist investor is simply a gadfly, noisy perhaps, but
just a gadfly. And if we suppress proxy contests, we close down the
most important channel for managerial accountability and corporate
legitimacy.
The proposal does this in at least three ways. First, it shortens to
five calendar days the “10-day window” following a party’s acquisition
of 5 percent of an issuer’s securities. Since purchases subsequent to
a 13D filing will impound the expected gains from shareholder
engagement, shortening the window will in many cases significantly
reduce the activist’s potential economic return and thus will probably
reduce the number of engagements, especially for smaller issuers.
Second, the proposal would classify the “underlying” shares of a
cash-settled derivative as beneficially owned by the long party on the
swap. Combined with the shortened disclosure window, this will in in
many cases significantly reduce the activist’s potential economic
return and thus is likely to reduce the number of engagements. Third,
the proposal would create a nebulous definition of a “group” that
would chill the kind of persuasive interactions that are essential to
a successful proxy contest in light of the heavily institutional share
ownership of many corporations.
Let me add some detail. For activist challenges to large
capitalization companies, the 10- day window may be of little
importance because the activist stake does not exceed 5 percent. But
for medium-cap and small-cap companies the 10-day window is important
because of its impact on the activist’s economic returns. How so?
Given the current pattern of institutional ownership, the costs of an
activist contest are relatively fixed. The cost of a detailed
analysis of a company’s business plan does not significantly increase
with the size of the company. Nor do the shareholder solicitation
costs, since these days, a credible proxy battle depends on reaching a
relatively small number of asset managers and institutional investors,
not the willingness to mail out proxy materials to millions of
shareholders. For an activist engagement with a large-cap firm,
earning a 7 percent return on a small (in percentage terms) position
will cover those fixed costs. But for a mid-cap or small-cap firm, a
larger percentage of ownership is required to cover those costs as
part of the activist’s economic return. For all but the largest
firms, however, liquidity for significant stock purchases is somewhat
limited. This means a party that seeks to accumulate a meaningful
block without significantly affecting the market price needs a longer
trading period.[1]
This where the 10-day window becomes important: It provides enough
trading days for the activist to acquire an economically sufficient
position in a company’s stock.
To be clear, the positions typically acquired by activists over the
10-day period do not amount to a control block, which was a concern of
the Williams Act. Indeed, the Williams Act initially made 10
percent the triggering ownership threshold, intending
thereby to add disclosure to the notice provision of section 16(a) of
the 1934 Act. Although the legislative history is sparse, the change
in 1970 to 5 percent was apparently triggered by the practice of
prospective tender offerors of acquiring 9+ percent before then
launching their bid.[2] A
10 percent position is even less of a control threat today than in
1968 both because of the domination of institutional ownership and
because of the poison pill, possessed in shadow form by all companies
even if not formally adopted. This generally has limited activist
accumulations (except in the rare case) to less than 10 percent.
There are two objections to a 10-day window: first, that it enhances
the extent of “information asymmetry” between the activist and
uninformed market participants and, second, that it facilitates the
formation of so-called “wolf packs.” The “wolves” may be thought of
as risk arbitrageurs who simply want the activist initiative to
succeed so they can realize a short term gain. Some believe that,
after the activist has acquired its desired block, the activist
facilitates the shift of stock into the hands of such
outcome-motivated parties through strategic tipping.
The SEC seems very concerned about wolf packs because it would include
tippees in the “group” whose stock ownership must be aggregated for
other purposes under the proposed rule.
In my view, an activist is entitled to full economic return on the
information that it has generated. As to information asymmetry in
transactions with an activist, the SEC ought not target it any more
than information asymmetry in transactions with a skilled and highly
reputed investor whose 13F reports produce a market reaction. This
information asymmetry is bound up with an economic reward for
activism, without which activism will cease. Tippees are different.
I’ve argued that activists serve the useful role of “potentiating
institutional voice;” teeing up questions about the company’s current
strategy and operational skill for resolution by the longterm
institutional holders whose business model makes them “rationally
reticent.”[3]
Parties who are trying to capture the information asymmetry from an
activist’s tip will have a different motivation from the longterm
holders in this model. They will be biased in favor of the activist’s
proposal to realize the immediate gain and to gain a reputation as a
reliable supporter, to keep the flow of tips coming.
I have serious doubts about the frequency of wolf packs and the
purported practice of tipping such investors to gain supporters of the
activist intervention. But here is a substitute proposal that both
preserves the activist’s ability to profit from information that it
generates while reducing the risk that obviously troubles the SEC:
Leave the present 10-day window but impose a prohibition on tipping
by an activist as soon as it reaches the 5 percent disclosure
threshold until it files a 13D. Such a rule would leverage the
incentives of the activist in appropriate ways. Until it has finished
it own acquisitions, the activist is highly unlikely to tip any other
party, because another’s substantial buying activity and the related
information leaks will raise the activist’s own acquisition costs and
thus reduce its rewards. After it has finished its own acquisitions,
until it has filed at 13D, the proposed rule would bar the activist
from tipping others.[4]
Another piece of the proposal, Rule 13d-3(e), would deem the long
party on a total return swap to be the beneficial owner of the
underlying equity securities. The argument against finding
“beneficial ownership” is that this cash-settled arrangement gives the
activist more “skin in the game,” which adds to the activist’s
incentives “to get it right” in its activism campaign, without
increasing the activist’s ability to directly affect the outcome
through additional voting power. Some contend that a total return
swap works differently in practice: The securities industry
counterparty will acquire target securities to hedge its swap
obligation, will vote such securities in accord with its customer’s
wishes, and stands ready to unwind the swap at its customer’s
request. This functionally gives the activist additional voting power
and an option on the securities and thus the potential to assert
voting rights directly. Of course, industry participants have
vociferously challenged these contentions as a factual matter.
One way out of these conflicting factual claims is a “safe harbor”
that would exempt from beneficial ownership swaps and cash-settled
derivatives that cannot obtain voting rights. For example, consider
securities that are subject to a “qualifying swap agreement” pursuant
to which (1) the securities industry counterparty agrees to vote
shares acquired as a hedge in proportion to votes cast by other
shareholders (“mirrored voting”) and (2) the parties agree that the
swap may not be unwound until after the record date of the proxy
contest linked to the activist campaign. As to shares associated with
such a “qualifying” total return swap, there can be no doubt that the
activist has neither voting control nor a right to acquire, both of
which have been traditionally associated with “beneficial ownership.”
Such an arrangement isolates the economic upside of successful
activism without reducing the decision-making power of the longterm
holders.
As to the “group” concepts in the proposal, frankly there is little
good to say. If the SEC has a legitimate concern, it is with parties
that have been drawn into the activism campaign by the lure of tip
before the filing of the 13D, the so-called wolf pack. I have
attempted to deal with that issue previously with an anti-tipping
rule. The commission seems to think that “group” formation should
extend beyond an explicit or implicit agreement to all parties “that
act as a group.” I think the most natural reading of section13(d)(3)
includes an explicit or implicit agreement. The statute reads, “When
two or more persons act as a partnership, limited partnership,
syndicate, or other
group….” (emphasis added). So far as I am aware,
“partnerships, limited partnerships, and syndicates” are founded on
agreement, express or implied, so in embracing “or other group,”
I think the statute embraces that essential feature. Any “group”
concept that goes beyond “agreement,” explicit or implicit, sets a
trap for the unwary and could chill legitimate activity. The effort
to provide additional guidance is likely to involve the SEC in either
unsatisfying no-action practice or multiple enforcement actions that
will take the definition outside of the commission’s purview into the
courts. This cannot be the best use of scarce commission resources.
The SEC’s rules (and its background explanations) would result in the
phrase “act as” having two different meanings. One meaning, in the
statute, is, limited to actions that involve partnerships, limited
partnerships, syndicates, and other groups. But the rules (and
explanatory gloss) seemingly use the same phrase, “act as,” to
indicate something much broader, sweeping up other activities that
involve actions and communications based on the vague notion of
“influencing control” coupled with an ex post assessment of whether
communications or actions were undertaken with this purpose or
effect. Frankly this second reading really means to reach parties who
act “as [if
they were] a group,” an impermissible extension of the
statutory language to reach parties who have not created or joined a
group.
The deep mischief of the SEC’s “group” definition is shown by the
effort to create an “acting as a group” carve-out in proposed rule
13d-6(c) that would permit shareholders to communicate with one
another, unless such communications “are undertaken with the purpose
or the effect of changing or influencing control of the issuer and are
not made in connection with … any transaction having such purpose or
effect.” This rule would chill the kind of shareholder communications
that are central to a proxy contest. Proxy contests, unlike tender
offers, are about persuasion. A
shareholder facing a tender offer needs to decide only whether the
offer is above the shareholder’s reservation price for the security.
If the tender offeror’s business plan is unsound, that’s of little
concern to an exiting shareholder. A proxy contest is altogether
different: The shareholder stays aboard for the ride. Consultation
among fellow shareholders and discussion with the activist are an
essential part of the story. I do not think the SEC has been
sufficiently careful in its “group” definition to avoid harm to the
U.S. system of corporate governance.
With the rise of ESG activism, the next period is likely to see many
proxy contests that put at issue the “purpose” of U.S. public
companies and that may seek “change” through director election
contests. I think it unwise for the SEC to put in place rules that
destabilize the existing and reasonably well-understood rules of
behavior by shareholders, including institutional investors and asset
managers.
ENDNOTES
[1] See
Pierre Collin-Dufresne and Vyacheslav Fos, Do Prices Reveal the
Presence of Informed Trading?, 70 J. Fin. 1555 (2015). This
consideration dominates the argument about technological advances in
registering trading activity.
[2] See
Note, Section 13(d) and Disclosure of Corporate Equity Ownership, 119
U. Pa. L. Rev. 853, 862-64, 865 n. 56 (1971).
[4] This
appears to be the intended result of proposed Rule 13d-5(b)(ii) et
seq. that would make such a tippee a member of the activism “group”
while imposing an unworkable burden on the tipper of monitoring the
transactions in target securities of a party with which it has no
agreement. Rule 14e-3 captures the spirit but imposes the obligation
on the tippee not to trade rather than on the activism proponent to
refrain from divulging information about the intended activist
engagement to parties who it should reasonably believe will use that
information to purchase target stock before the filing of a 13D. Any
rule should have a carve out for swap dealers who are purchasing
securities to hedge a long swap position entered into by the activism
proponent.
This post comes to us from Jeffrey N. Gordon, the Richard Paul Richman
Professor of Law at Columbia University and co-director of the
Millstein Center for Global Markets and Corporate Ownership.
This Forum program was open, free of charge,
to anyone concerned with investor interests in the
development of marketplace standards for expanded access to
information for securities valuation and shareholder voting
decisions. As stated
in the posted
Conditions of Participation, the purpose of this public
Forum's program was to provide decision-makers with access to
information and a free exchange of views on the issues
presented in the program's Forum
Summary. Each
participant was expected to make independent use of
information obtained through the Forum, subject to the
privacy rights of other participants. It is a Forum
rule that participants will not be identified or quoted
without their explicit permission.
This Forum program was initiated in 2012 in
collaboration with The Conference Board and with
Thomson Reuters support of communication technologies to address
issues and objectives defined by participants in the 2010 "E-Meetings"
program relevant to broad public interests in marketplace
practices. The website is being maintained to provide
continuing reports of the issues addressed in the program,
as summarized in the
January 5, 2015 Forum Report of Conclusions.
Inquiries about this Forum
program and requests to be included in its distribution list
may be addressed to
access@shareholderforum.com.
The information provided to
Forum participants is intended for their private reference,
and permission has not been granted for the republishing of
any copyrighted material. The material presented on this web
site is the responsibility of
Gary Lutin, as chairman of the Shareholder Forum.
Shareholder Forum™
is a trademark owned by The Shareholder Forum, Inc., for the
programs conducted since 1999 to support investor access to
decision-making information. It should be noted that we have
no responsibility for the services that Broadridge Financial
Solutions, Inc., introduced for review in the Forum's
2010 "E-Meetings" program and has since been offering
with the “Shareholder Forum” name, and we have asked
Broadridge to use a different name that does not suggest our
support or endorsement.