Forum reference:
Legal experts' failure to distinguish between
investor definitions of market pricing and intrinsic value in appraisal analyses
For the cases on which this
series of articles (in parts 1, 2
and 3, below) focuses, see
|
Sources
Part 1:
Law360, July 28, 2015 article
Part 2:
Law360, July 29, 2015 article
Part 3:
Law360, July 30, 2015 article |
A Study Of Recent Delaware Appraisal
Decisions: Part 1
|
Philip Richter |
|
Robert C. Schwenkel
|
Law360, New
York (July 28, 2015, 4:38 PM ET) -- There has been much ado about the
Delaware Chancery Court’s recent reliance on the merger price to determine
fair value in appraisal cases.
The Delaware statute defines fair value of a company as its going-concern
value immediately prior to the merger, excluding value arising from the
merger itself. In the past, the court has relied on standard financial
analyses of going-concern value (primarily discounted cash flow (DCF) and
comparable companies or transactions analyses). In a break with past
practice, however, several times in recent months, the court has relied
primarily or exclusively on the merger price to determine fair value.
The Court’s Reliance
on the Merger Price is Still Limited
Narrow Set of Circumstances (Two-Prong Test). The court has
emphasized that it will rely primarily on the merger price only when both
(1) the merger price is particularly reliable as an indication of value
because an effective market check was part of the sale process and (2) the
financial valuation methodologies are particularly unreliable because the
available inputs — projections and comparable companies or transactions —
are unreliable.
Small Number of Cases. There have been only four cases in
which the court has relied primarily on the merger price.
Factual Context. The factual context in each of these cases
included (1) an especially strong sale process — a public auction with
competing bids in three of the four cases and, in the fourth case, a
thorough public shopping of the company to obtain a white knight bidder
(although no competing bid emerged); (2) no competing bid being made after
announcement of the merger; and (3) a merger price that represented a
significant premium above the unaffected stock price.
The Court’s Approach
Has Been Consistent in the Appraisal Decisions This Quarter
The court’s appraisal decisions this past quarter have produced varying
outcomes — with the court determining fair value to be:
-
equal to the merger price — in Merlin v. Autoinfo (Apr. 30, 2015);
-
slightly below the merger price — in Longpath v.
Ramtron (June 30, 2015); and
-
significantly above the merger price — in Owen v. Cannon (June 17,
2015).
The court’s
approach has been consistent, however. In AutoInfo and Ramtron, both of
which involved arm’s length transactions with an effective market check
and with unreliable valuation analysis inputs (as well as a merger price
that represented a significant premium to the unaffected stock price), the
court relied primarily on the merger price — and found fair value to be
equal (or very close) to the merger price.
In Cannon, which involved an interested transaction (a squeeze-out merger)
with no market check (as well as a merger price well below the value
indicated by third-party valuations received by the company), the court
relied on a DCF analysis — and its fair-value determination represented a
60 percent premium over the merger price. It remains to be seen to what
extent the court may expand its use of the merger price as the primary
factor in determining fair value.
Before the court ever expressly used the merger price to determine fair
value, the court, stating that it was relying on DCF analyses,
consistently determined fair value to be equal or close to the merger
price in disinterested transactions in which there had been an effective
market check (and often determined fair value to be significantly higher
than the merger price in interested transactions without a market check).
Thus, while not expressly relying on the merger price, the actual results
of the court’s past appraisal decisions clearly suggest that, when there
has been an effective market check, the merger price has always been a
strong (albeit unacknowledged) factor in the court’s considerations.
Open Issues
Will the court’s increased inclination to use the merger price to
determine fair value expand to include any transaction with an effective
market check, whether or not there are reliable inputs for a financial
analysis?
So far, the court has used the merger price as the primary or exclusive
basis for determining fair value only in those cases involving
transactions that meet both prongs of the test noted above (an effective
market check and unavailability of reliable inputs for financial
analyses). Yet, reliance on the merger price whenever there has been an
effective market check — thus, even if, for example, the company
projections are reliable — no doubt holds allure. That approach would
short-cut the considerable difficulties inherent in a DCF analysis.
A DCF analysis can yield widely varying results depending on the selection
of the numerous required inputs for the analysis. These inputs are often
uncertain or subjective (including, for example, the company’s long-term
projections and the appropriate discount rate). Moreover, a small change
in any of them can yield a significant change in the result. Even when a
DCF analysis is conducted in a cooperative, nonlitigation context, there
may be considerable uncertainty about the reliability of the result — and
the court has often expressed frustration, most recently in Ramtron, with
“litigation-driven valuations” submitted by the parties’ experts.
Moreover, as noted, the results, as a practical matter, would not
necessarily differ from those that now pertain.
How strong would the market check have to be for the court to use
the merger price to determine fair value in a case involving an interested
transaction?
To date, the appraisal cases involving interested transactions have
included, in the court’s view, no (or weak) market checks. Moreover, the
amount by which the court’s fair value determinations (using financial
valuation analyses) have exceeded the merger price has generally
corresponded to the apparent strength of the sale process (even though the
process is logically irrelevant to a DCF or other financial analysis of
going-concern value). It remains to be seen whether the court would accord
to an interested transaction with an effective market check the same
treatment as a disinterested transaction with an effective market check.
Would the merger price or the financial valuation take precedence in
the case of a transaction in which there had been an effective market
check but also reliable financial analyses — and the financial valuation
exceeds the merger price?
If the court were to expand its use of the merger price to all
transactions with an effective market check, how would the court respond
if the financial valuations — if based on reliable company projections and
sufficiently comparable companies and transactions — lead to values
materially in excess of the merger price? Clearly, in such a case, either
the “effective market check” would not in fact have been effective or
there would have been a “market failure” for some reason. Presumably, the
course the court would choose in these circumstances would depend on the
court’s view of the reason for the discrepancy between the merger price
and the financial valuations.
Key Points
-
Consistency of Results in
Appraisal Cases.
The court has been, and continues to be, consistent in awarding
appraisal amounts equal (or close) to the merger price in disinterested
transactions in which the sale process included an effective market
check — whether the court has utilized the merger price or a DCF
analysis as the basis for determining fair value. The court continues to
be consistent in awarding appraisal amounts that significantly exceed
the merger price only in interested transactions without an effective
market check.
-
Use of the Merger Price Under
Narrow Circumstances.
Although the court has now relied on the merger price as the sole or
primary basis for determining value in four recent cases, in each of
these cases there was not only (1) an effective market check, but also
(2) the court viewed the standard financial analyses (DCF and
comparables analyses) as being particularly unreliable because
management projections were deemed to be unreliable for a variety of
reasons and there were not sufficiently comparable companies or
transactions.
-
Effect of Increased Use of
the Merger Price.
As noted, the court’s
increased used of the merger price in disinterested transactions with an
effective market check may not change the results in these cases.
Further, in our view, the increased use of the merger price may or may
not discourage appraisal arbitrage overall but, in any event, should
tend to drive appraisal claims away from disinterested transactions with
an effective market check (unless accompanied by indications that the
market check was not in fact effective) and to those transactions with
the most potential for an award significantly above the merger price.
-
Effectiveness of Market Check
When There is a Single Bidder.
The court has viewed a public auction process with competitive bidding
as an effective market check that supports the court’s use of the merger
price to determine appraised fair value. In Ramtron, even though no
competing bid emerged during the company’s search for a white knight
buyer after the company had received an unsolicited bid, the court
viewed the company’s “lengthy” and “public” shopping of the company
(during which it contacted every party that the company believed might
be interested) to have been an effective market check.
-
Continued Confusion About
Adjustments to Exclude Merger-Specific Value.
The court’s more frequent use of the merger price to determine fair
value necessarily focuses more attention on the long-neglected issue of
adjustments to the merger price to exclude merger-specific value from
the appraisal award (as is statutorily mandated). In AutoInfo, the court
articulated a new burden of proof that has the potential to provide
effective guidance to parties seeking to establish the need for an
adjustment. Although inconsistent with the general approach in appraisal
cases of both parties and the court itself having a burden to establish
fair value, the court stated that the party arguing for an adjustment to
exclude value arising from merger-specific synergies would have the
burden of establishing the merger-specific nature of the synergies and
their value. We note that, nonetheless, the next appraisal decision,
Ramtron, indicates that, where both parties propose an adjustment
amount, the court may select the amount it considers to be more
reasonable (which the court in Ramtron did without analysis or much
explanation), even if the burden of proof has not been met. We note that
the court still has not addressed (and parties to appraisal actions
still have not raised) the issue of whether all or part of a control
premium included in the merger price is merger-specific value that
should be excluded.
-
Reliability of Projections —
No Change in the Court’s Approach.
The court continues to find projections to be unreliable when they are
not prepared by management in the ordinary course of business.
Please see
below our charts summarizing the outcome of each appraisal case since 2010
and a list of our other articles on appraisal.
Parts 2 and 3 of this article will be published here in the coming days,
covering additional explanation and discussion of the key points noted
above; summaries of AutoInfo, Cannon and Ramtron; and practice points
relating to adjustments to the merger price, projections and other
appraisal-related issues arising out of these decisions.
—By Steven Epstein, Arthur Fleischer Jr., Peter S. Golden, Brian T.
Mangino, Philip Richter, Robert C. Schwenkel, John E. Sorkin and Gail
Weinstein,
Fried Frank Harris Shriver & Jacobson LLP
Steven Epstein,
Peter Golden,
Philip Richter,
Robert Schwenkel and
John Sorkin are partners in Fried
Frank's New York office.
Brian Mangino is a partner in
Washington, D.C.
Arthur Fleischer and
Gail Weinstein are senior counsel in
New York.
The opinions expressed are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily
reflect the views of the firm, its clients, or Portfolio Media Inc., or
any of its or their respective affiliates. This article is for general
information purposes and is not intended to be and should not be taken as
legal advice.
|
A Study Of Recent Delaware Appraisal
Decisions: Part 2
|
Steven Epstein |
|
John E. Sorkin
|
Law360, New
York (July 29, 2015, 4:38 PM ET) -- In
part 1 of this article, we outlined
the key points relating to the latest Delaware appraisal decisions: Merlin
v. Autoinfo (Apr. 30, 2015), Owen v. Cannon (June 17, 2015), and Longpath
v.
Ramtron (June 30, 2015). Specifically,
we noted that, although the Chancery Court in recent months has expanded
its use of the merger price in the underlying transaction as a basis for
determining appraised “fair value,” the court’s reliance on the merger
price has been expressly limited to a narrow set of circumstances. We
noted further that, at the same time, while the most recent appraisal
decisions have resulted in varying outcomes — with the court determining
fair value to be equal to the merger price (in Merlin), significantly
above the merger price (in Cannon), and slightly below the merger price
(in Ramtron) — the court’s approach has been consistent.
In this article, we provide further explanation and discussion of the key
points arising out of AutoInfo, Cannon and Ramtron. Part 3 of this article
will be published here in the coming days, covering practice points
arising out of these decisions.
Consistency of the Chancery
Court's Results in Appraisal Awards
Interested Transactions Without an Effective Market Check
The court has been consistent in determining fair value to be
significantly above the merger price only in interested transactions
(i.e., transactions involving, for example, a controller or a
parent-subsidiary or squeeze-out merger) without an effective market
check. Moreover, the amount of the premium above the merger price
represented by the fair-value determination in these cases has
corresponded with the extent of the market check. The premiums in cases
involving interested transactions that included no market check ranged
from 60 percent to 150 percent, while the premiums in cases involving
transactions that included some (albeit, in each case, a weak) market
check were just under 20 percent.
Disinterested Transactions with a Market Check
Irrespective of the valuation methodology utilized by the court, the court
has been consistent in determining fair value to be not significantly
above the merger price in disinterested transactions with a market check.
In the disinterested transactions that have included an effective market
check, the court has determined fair value to be equal (or close) to the
merger price. In the disinterested transactions in which the court did not
comment on the sale process (although, we note, in each of these there
appeared to be no, or only a weak, market check), the court has determined
fair value to be above, but not significantly above, the merger price
(specifically, premiums of 9 percent and 16 percent above the merger
price, and, in one case with an unusual fact situation, 14 percent below
the merger price).
Methodology to Determine
Fair Value
The Delaware appraisal statute defines fair value for appraisal purposes
as going-concern value of a company immediately preceding the merger,
excluding any value arising from the merger itself.
Use of the Merger Price
The court now primarily or exclusively relies on the merger price to
determine fair value when (1) the merger price is a particularly reliable
indication of value because it has been established through a sale process
that included an effective market check and (2) the standard financial
valuation analyses (discounted cash flow (DCF) and comparables analyses)
are particularly unreliable because (a) the available company projections
(the primary input for a DCF analysis) are unreliable and (b) there are
not sufficiently comparable transactions or companies (for meaningful
input to a comparables analysis). All of the recent cases meeting these
parameters have involved disinterested transactions.
Use of DCF Analysis
In the case of interested transactions, and in the case of disinterested
transactions in which either prong of the two-part test has not been
satisfied, the court has relied primarily or exclusively on a DCF analysis
to determine appraised fair value. As noted, in these cases,
notwithstanding the potential inherent in a DCF analysis for wide
variability of the results, and notwithstanding the logical irrelevance to
a DCF analysis of the nature of the transaction or the sale process, the
court’s results have been significantly above the merger price in the case
of interested transactions and not significantly above the merger price in
the case of disinterested transactions (with the amount of any premium
above the merger price corresponding to the apparent strength of the sale
process).
Open Issues
We note that key open issues remaining include: Will the court’s increased
inclination to use the merger price to determine fair value expand to
include any transaction with an effective market check, whether or not
there are reliable inputs for a financial analysis? How strong would the
market check have to be for the court to use the merger price to determine
fair value in a case involving an interested transaction? Would the merger
price or the financial valuation take precedence in the case of a
transaction in which there had been an effective market check but also
reliable financial analyses — and the financial valuation exceeds the
merger price?
Effectiveness of Market
Check
Prior to Ramtron, each case in which the court utilized the merger price
to determine fair value after finding that there had been an effective
market check involved a public auction with competing bids. In Ramtron,
the court viewed the company’s aggressive public shopping of the company
to find a white knight buyer to be an effective market check — even though
no competing bidder emerged. Notably, the $3.10 merger price the company
ultimately agreed with the unsolicited bidder, after five separate price
increases, represented a 71 percent premium over the unaffected stock
price and a 25 percent increase over the unsolicited bidder’s initial
offer price. The court found that the nonemergence of competing bids was a
result of the company’s “operative reality” rather than “any shortcomings
of the process.” The court noted that no party made a competing bid even
at the time that the unsolicited bidder’s offer was 42 cents below the
final merger price.
Continued Uncertainty About
Adjustments to the Merger Price to Exclude Merger-Specific Value
The Delaware appraisal statute mandates that any value arising from the
merger itself be excluded from appraised fair value. In the cases in which
the court has utilized the merger price as a basis for fair value, the
court has acknowledged that merger-specific value must be “backed out.”
However, the court invariably has not made adjustments — sometimes simply
ignoring the issue and sometimes indicating that the parties had not
argued for or established a sufficient basis for an adjustment.
There are difficulties inherent in determining what is a merger-specific
synergy and how to calculate the value it represents. These difficulties,
as a practical matter, may account for the court’s reluctance to make
adjustments to exclude merger-specific value when the merger price is used
as the primary or sole basis for determining fair value.
Further, the court has not addressed (and the parties to appraisal actions
have not raised) the complicated issue of whether all or part of a control
premium is merger-specific value that should be excluded from a
determination of fair value.
AutoInfo: Court Establishes a New Burden on the Party Advocating an
Adjustment for Merger Synergies
In AutoInfo, the court has provided what appears to be new, albeit
limited, guidance on this issue. The court placed on the party arguing for
an adjustment a burden to establish the need for, and amount of, the
adjustment. We note that, generally, the court has characterized the
appraisal statute as placing a burden on both parties and on the court to
determine fair value. Thus, no presumptions have been applied by the court
based on one or the other party’s failing to provide convincing evidence
with respect to one or more parts of the determination of fair value.
Rather, the court has viewed itself as having the burden of determining
whether to rely on one party’s view or the other’s or, if it finds neither
persuasive, than to form its own view. In AutoInfo, the court appears to
have departed from that approach in connection with the issue of
adjustments to the merger price when it is used as the basis for fair
value.
In AutoInfo, the respondent company’s expert had argued that a downward
adjustment should be made to the merger price to exclude the cost savings
the acquiror anticipated from eliminating public company costs and
reducing executive compensation. These savings were reflected in the base
case projections the acquiror had developed and used internally. Following
its usual course, the court did not make any adjustment to exclude
merger-specific synergies. The court stated that the record had not
established precisely the nature of the anticipated cost savings (thus,
according to the court, it could not be determined whether they were
merger-specific) or the reliability of the estimated amount of the
savings. The court, in effect, established a presumption against an
adjustment for anticipated cost savings unless the company demonstrates
that the anticipated savings are merger-specific and that the court can
have confidence in the amount.
It remains to be seen how rigorous a standard the court will apply in
determining whether a record sufficiently supports an adjustment being
made to the merger price. Given the court’s strong reluctance to date to
make any adjustments when the merger price has been used to determine fair
value, and given that the court rejected any adjustment in AutoInfo even
though the record (while not fully developed) appeared to be sufficient to
indicate that some adjustment would be required, we expect that the court
may continue to apply a restrictive standard.
Ramtron: Court Chooses Between Parties’ Proposed Adjustments
(Selecting Only a Nominal Adjustment)
In Ramtron, the court rejected the respondent’s two proposed methods of
determining an adjustment to exclude merger-specific synergies (both of
which indicated a 34 cents per share adjustment of the $3.10 merger
price). We note that, if the company had the benefit of the court’s
discussion of adjustments in AutoInfo, it may have been possible for the
company to have developed a more acceptable methodology. With little
discussion, the court characterized the petitioner’s proposed nominal
adjustment (3 cents per share) as “better conform[ing] to the evidence
adduced at trial” — even though, the court stated, that adjustment “may
understate” the merger-specific synergies.
The court noted the petitioner’s testimony that, in addition to “positive
synergies” anticipated from the merger (such as cost savings), significant
“negative synergies” (i.e., negative effects on revenue, as well as
transaction costs in the range of 10-15 percent of revenue) were also
expected. Therefore, the court appeared to believe that the petitioner’s
nominal adjustment (although likely too low) made more sense than the
respondent’s proposed significant adjustment (which, the court noted,
represented more than 10 percent of the merger price).
Notwithstanding the burden of proof established in AutoInfo, the court in
Ramtron simply selected what it viewed as the more reasonable of the two
proposals, without regard to the burden of proof. In our view, it may be
that the court will take this approach only in limited situations — such
as where, as was the case in Ramtron, significant negative synergies are
anticipated, both parties propose adjustment amounts, one amount does not
take into account the negative synergies, and the other amount is nominal.
Reliability of Projections —
No Change in the Court’s Approach
The court generally views as reliable projections that are prepared by
management in the ordinary course of business. These are viewed as
reliable because management ordinarily has the best first-hand knowledge
of a company’s operations and, when prepared in the ordinary course, the
projections typically reflect management’s best estimate of the company’s
future performance and are not tainted by distorting influences or
post-merger hindsight.
The court has viewed management projections as unreliable when they:
-
were prepared outside the
ordinary course of business;
-
were prepared by a management
team that never before prepared similar projections;
-
were prepared in anticipation
of litigation or an appraisal action, or with some other motive (for
example, to protect their jobs or to increase the apparent value of the
company in a sale process);
-
were viewed by management
itself as unreliable; and/or
-
were based on unusual company
or industry factors that were so speculative as to make forecasting
nearly impossible.
AutoInfo
and Ramtron: Unreliable Projections
In Ramtron and AutoInfo, the court rejected use of a DCF analysis to
determine fair value in part because the court deemed the management’s
projections to be unreliable.
In Ramtron, the court deemed the projections to be unreliable because they
were prepared by a new management team (with the CEO, chief financial
officer and all other senior management having been at the company for
less than two years); the team used a new methodology (that the team
appeared to view, without confidence, as a “new and unfamiliar process”);
and the company had previously only ever prepared short-term forecasts
(which the company itself had recently characterized as having limited
reliability).
Further, the court found that the projections, prepared while the company
was in the process of trying to defend against a hostile takeover bid,
were prepared in anticipation of possible future disputes and seeking
white knights; in addition, the projections did not accord with the
reality of the business in numerous respects. Moreover, the company itself
did not rely on the projections in the ordinary course of its business
(having prepared other projections for managing the company’s finances,
including providing information to the company’s bank). Importantly, the
court criticized the parties’ “litigation-driven” valuations, including
the petitioner’s “eyebrow-raising DCF,” which relied on projections the
expert had presumed were overly optimistic and yet still yielded a result
2 cents below the merger price.
In AutoInfo, the court found that the company’s projections were
unreliable because management had been specifically directed to “paint an
‘aggressively optimistic’ picture” for the purpose of generating more
interest in, and a better price for, the company in its sale process. In
addition, management had never before prepared projections, “had no
confidence in its ability to forecast” the company’s future performance,
and “perceived its attempt [to forecast] as ‘a bit of a chuckle and a
joke.’”
Cannon: High Bar for Company to Disavow Its Projections
In Cannon (an interested transaction), the court and both of the parties
utilized a DCF analysis to determine fair value. The court rejected the
company’s attempt to disavow the projections that had been prepared by the
company’s president in favor of projections later created by the company’s
expert. The expert’s projections, which had been prepared in anticipation
of a mediation of the parties’ dispute with respect to the forced buyback
of the petitioner’s shares, projected less growth in the company than the
projections that the company had prepared earlier in anticipation of
offering to buy back the petitioner’s shares. The court deemed the
expert’s projections to be unreliable because they were prepared in
anticipation of litigation.
While the president’s projections had been prepared for the purpose of
determining the offer price for the contemplated forced buyback of the
petitioner’s shares (either through his agreement or a squeeze-out
merger), the petitioner did not argue that they were unreliable on this
basis, but argued instead that the president’s projections were more
reliable than the expert’s revised projections.
The court agreed, finding that the following factors supported the
reliability of the president’s projections: (1) although the projections
had not been prepared by a management team but by the president alone, the
president had a thorough knowledge of the company and its prospects, and
other management input was obtained through weekly discussions with the
president about results, developments and prospects; (2) the president
had, over a three-year period, updated and revised the projections to
reflect actual results and new developments; (3) the president had
submitted the projections to financing sources (here, the court emphasized
that it will place great weight on projections that have been provided to
financing sources, as it is a federal felony to knowingly obtain funds
from a financial institution by false or fraudulent pretenses or
representations); and (4) it was unlikely that the president’s projections
were too high, as he had an incentive to make the projections as low as
possible since they were prepared for the purpose of setting the price for
the buyback of the petitioner’s shares.
The court rejected the respondent’s arguments that, based on principles
discussed in previous Chancery Court decisions, the projections prepared
by its president were unreliable. The court distinguished the previous
decisions as follows:
-
CKx.
In Huff v. CKx (2013), the court viewed the company’s projections as
unreliable because a projected increase in licensing fees under a
material, to-be-negotiated contract was so speculative and the initial
estimates of those revenues had been markedly lower than the projections
provided to potential buyers and lenders. By contrast, the court noted,
in Cannon, although Cannon had argued that its prospects had dimmed, it
had not identified any particular line item or line of business in the
projections that was so uncertain as to undermine the integrity of the
overall projections.
-
JustCare.
In Gearreald v. Just Care (2012), the court viewed the company’s
projections as unreliable because the company had never before prepared
multiyear projections. The court distinguished the situation in ESG by
noting that, even though the company had not generally prepared
projections in the ordinary course of business, the president’s
projections had been prepared (and updated and revised) over three
years; that he had been confident enough in them to provide them to
banks in connection with financing the buyout; and that they had been
created in part with the assistance of a financial adviser with whom the
president had reviewed the revenue growth assumptions.
-
Nine Systems.
In In re Nine Systems (2014), the court viewed a set of one-year
projections as unreliable because the projections were inconsistent with
the company’s recent performance (specifically, management had
“overestimated ... revenues even two months away ... by more than a
factor of three”). By contrast, in Cannon, the court noted, the
company’s performance in the months just preceding the merger was in
line with the projections.
Summary of Most
Recent Cases: AutoInfo, Cannon and Ramtron
AutoInfo — In this disinterested transaction involving a
competitive public auction, the court:
-
used the merger price to
determine fair value (with a DCF analysis as a double-check);
-
found the sale process to
have been thorough;
-
found the management
projections unreliable because they were prepared with a view to
marketing the company;
-
imposed a new burden with
respect to adjustments to the merger price to exclude merger-specific
synergies; and
-
determined fair value to be
equal to the merger price.
In AutoInfo,
the merger price, $1.05 per share, had been established through a public
auction process conducted at arm’s length by a special committee with an
independent financial adviser. The company and its financial adviser had
aggressively shopped the company; the merger agreement was entered into
with the bidder that had by far the highest indication of interest
(although, after that bidder uncovered alleged accounting, financial and
other irregularities during due diligence, the price was renegotiated to
an amount slightly below the amount at which some of the other indications
of interest had been); and no competing bid emerged during the almost
two-month post-signing period. The court rejected the company’s
projections as unreliable because management had been instructed to
prepare aggressively optimistic projections as they would be used to
market the company. The court rejected the petitioner’s comparable
companies analysis because of the much larger size of the companies
included and their different business model (store-based as opposed to the
company’s agent-based model).
The petitioner’s expert had argued that fair value was $2.60 per share,
based one-third each on a DCF analysis, comparable company analysis using
a historical-based multiple, and a comparable company analysis using a
forward-looking multiple. The respondent’s expert had argued that fair
value was 97 cents, based on the merger price, adjusted downward to
exclude cost savings arising from the merger. The court based fair value
on the merger price — and also conducted its own DCF analysis as a
double-check on the merger price (which yielded a result slightly below
the merger price: 93 cents). The court rejected any adjustment to the
merger price to exclude merger-specific synergies, reasoning that the
party arguing for those adjustments (the company) had a burden (that it
had not met) to establish the nature and amount of the synergies alleged
to be merger-specific before any adjustment could be made.
Cannon — In this interested transaction involving a
squeeze-out merger at a price far below the value indicated in third-party
valuations received by the company (and with no market check), the court:
-
used a DCF analysis to
determine fair value (as had both parties);
-
rejected the company’s
attempt to disavow (and lower) its projections; and
-
determined fair value to be
significantly higher than the merger price.
In Cannon, two
stockholder-directors of a Subchapter S corporation forcibly removed the
third stockholder-director (the petitioner) as president and, after
several failed attempts at repurchasing his shares, effected a squeeze-out
merger in which his shares were canceled. At the merger price, the
petitioner would have received $26.33 million for his interest. The
repurchase offers and the merger price for his interest were all far below
the value indicated in third-party valuations received by the company
throughout the relevant periods. The court utilized a DCF analysis to
determine fair value, yielding a result of $42.17 million — representing a
60 percent premium over the merger price. The result of the DCF analysis
conducted by the petitioner’s expert was $53.46 million, while the
respondents’ expert’s DCF result was $21.50 million. The difference in
results in the DCF analyses was primarily attributable to the different
projections utilized.
In addition, the petitioner had tax-affected the company’s earnings in the
analysis to compensate the petitioner for the loss of the tax advantage in
being a stockholder of a Subchapter S corporation. The court utilized the
projections prepared by the company’s new president (one of the two
stockholder-directors who planned the merger), rejecting the respondents’
arguments that their expert’s more conservative projections should be used
instead, and agreed with the petitioner that the Subchapter S corporation
earnings should be tax-affected.
Ramtron — In this disinterested transaction involving a
hostile takeover bid and a thorough search for a white knight buyer (with
no competing bidder having emerged), the court:
-
used the merger price to
determine fair value;
-
found the management
projections unreliable for a variety of reasons;
-
made a nominal adjustment to
the merger price for merger-specific synergies (without much
discussion); and
-
based on the nominal
adjustment, determined fair value to be just below the merger price.
In Ramtron, the company, after receiving an unsolicited bid, aggressively
shopped the company to find a white knight buyer, while rejecting the
unsolicited bid. No competing bids emerged over the three-month period and
the company ultimately agreed to a merger with the unsolicited bidder. The
merger price, $3.10 per share, represented a 75 percent premium over the
unaffected stock price and, after five separate increases in the bid
price, a 25 percent increase from the initial offer. The court rejected
the management projections as unreliable because, among other things, the
entire senior management team had been in place for a very short time; the
projections were prepared using a new methodology; the management
expressed uncertainty about the reliability of the projections and used
different projections to manage the company’s finances and provide
information to its bank; and the projections were prepared in anticipation
of potential litigation (including an appraisal action). The court
rejected the petitioner’s comparables analysis because it was comprised of
only two comparable companies and the multiples for each differed
significantly, making the average of the data points unreliable.
The petitioner’s expert had argued that fair value was $4.96 per share
(which was 274 percent of the unaffected stock price, the court noted),
based 80 percent on its DCF analysis (which yielded a result of $5.20) and
20 percent on its comparables analysis (which yielded a result of $3.99).
The respondents’ expert had argued that fair value was $2.76, based on the
merger price, adjusted downward to exclude cost savings arising from the
merger. The respondent’s expert argued, in the alternative, that fair
value, based on a DCF analysis utilizing management’s projections, was
$3.08. The court based fair value solely on the merger price and, with
little analysis or explanation, adjusted the merger price downward by the
3 cents that the petitioner proposed represented the merger-synergy
savings less the merger-synergy costs.
Please see
part 1 of the article for our charts
summarizing the outcome of each appraisal case since 2010 and a list of
our other articles on appraisal. Part 3 of this article, to be published
here in the coming days, will cover practice points relating to
adjustments to the merger price, projections and other appraisal-related
issues arising from AutoInfo, Cannon and Ramtron.
—By Steven Epstein, Arthur Fleischer Jr., Peter S. Golden, Brian T.
Mangino, Philip Richter, Robert C. Schwenkel, John E. Sorkin and Gail
Weinstein,
Fried Frank Harris Shriver & Jacobson LLP
Steven Epstein,
Peter Golden,
Philip Richter,
Robert Schwenkel and
John Sorkin are partners in Fried
Frank's New York office.
Brian Mangino is a partner in
Washington, D.C.
Arthur Fleischer and
Gail Weinstein are senior counsel in
New York.
The opinions expressed are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily
reflect the views of the firm, its clients, or Portfolio Media Inc., or
any of its or their respective affiliates. This article is for general
information purposes and is not intended to be and should not be taken as
legal advice.
|
A Study Of Recent Delaware Appraisal
Decisions: Part 3
|
Philip Richter |
|
Brian T. Mangino
|
Law360, New
York (July 30, 2015, 10:28 AM ET) -- In
part 1 of this article (published July
28), we outlined the key points relating to the latest Delaware appraisal
decisions: Merlin v. Autoinfo (Apr. 30, 2015), Owen v. Cannon (June 17,
2015), and Longpath v.
Ramtron (June 30, 2015). Specifically,
we noted that, although the Chancery Court in recent months has expanded
its use of the merger price in the underlying transaction as a basis for
determining appraised “fair value,” the court’s reliance on the merger
price has been expressly limited to a narrow set of circumstances. We
noted further that, at the same time, while the most recent appraisal
decisions have resulted in varying outcomes — with the court determining
fair value to be equal to the merger price (in AutoInfo), significantly
above the merger price (in Cannon), and slightly below the merger price
(in Ramtron) — the court’s approach has been consistent. In
part 2 of this article (published July
29), we provided further explanation and discussion of the key points
arising out of, as well as summaries of, AutoInfo, Cannon and Ramtron. In
this part 3, we provide practice points arising out of these decisions.
Key Practice Points for
Acquirors Relating to Adjustment of the Merger Price
Establish the Amount and Nature of the Expected Cost Savings
An acquiror should outline in some detail the cost savings expected from
the merger. References to anticipated savings embedded, for example, in
assumptions for projections or in an investment memorandum may not be
sufficient. The acquiror should identify what portion of the expected
savings is attributable to the merger itself.
For example, executive compensation reductions that are anticipated due to
the overlaps of executive positions at both companies (i.e., the merged
company will not need two CEOs, two chief financial officers, etc.) would
appear to be merger-specific. Reductions that are anticipated due to the
target’s already having implemented compensation reductions would not be
merger-specific. Reductions anticipated because the target’s compensation
scale is above market (so reductions could be achieved by the target
itself without the merger, but the target might not have thought of or
wanted to make those reductions) are more difficult to classify as
merger-specific or not.
The acquiror should consider identifying what part of its offer price is
based on expected merger-specific cost savings. Internal documents, and
those prepared by the company’s investment banker, should be carefully
reviewed so as to be consistent with the acquiror’s views of
merger-related cost savings.
Consider Establishing the Amount of the Control Premium
The merger price typically includes a control premium, all or part of
which logically is merger-specific and should be excluded from the court’s
determination of fair value. An acquiror should consider establishing a
foundation to support a determination as to what part of the merger price
is represented by a control premium. If the merger price is used to
determine fair value in an appraisal proceeding, the respondent company
should argue for a downward adjustment to exclude that amount. We are not
aware of parties to appraisal proceedings having made this argument and
the court has not addressed the issue. (Of course, the calculation of the
control premium amount could be complex because, for example, part of a
control premium may be attributable to merger synergies (and cannot be
counted twice in determining reductions).
Seek to Understand the Target Company’s Sale Process
The acquiror will have a better sense of the likely appraisal risk if it
understands the target’s sale process, including whether there was an
effective market check. The acquiror should consider requesting
information about the sale process from the target company’s general
counsel and seeking to review a draft of the target’s description of the
background of the transaction in its proxy statement or tender offer
statement.
Seek to Establish the Nature and Reliability of the Target’s
Projections
The acquiror will have a better sense of the likely appraisal risk if it
understands the target’s process in developing its projections. For
example, the acquiror should seek to understand: Does the company prepare
annual projections on a regular basis? What is the nature of those
projections (one-, three- or five-year)? Are the projections subject to
review by the board and what is the extent of the review? Were the
projections utilized in the sale process prepared in the ordinary course?
Are there any factors indicating that the projections utilized in the sale
process were prepared other than in the ordinary course? Are there any
factors indicating that the projections were modeled to be “aggressively
optimistic,” were prepared in anticipation of the sale process, or do not
reflect the management’s best view of the company’s future? What has
management said about its confidence in the projections and how has
management used the projections? Have the projections been provided to the
company’s banks or other financial institutions?
We note that, if a court utilizes the merger price to determine fair value
and requests adjustment proposals from the parties, the petitioner and the
company may wish to consider the game theory involved in proposing a lower
proposed adjustment (in the case of the company) or a nominal proposed
adjustment (in the case of the petitioner) insofar as it may affect the
court’s decision whether to reject both proposals as not satisfying the
burden of proof or to select what it views as the more reasonable between
the two proposals.
Key Practice Points From
Cannon
Stockholders Agreement Should Have Prevented the Squeeze-Out Merger
The petitioner argued that the merger violated the stockholders agreement
among the petitioner and the other two stockholders. That agreement
required that all three stockholders approve any “agreements or
transactions valued in excess of [$10,000]” and “any material changes in
the business of the Company.” The court declined to resolve the issue for
various reasons. We note, however, that the stockholders agreement could
have been drafted more clearly to prevent a squeeze-out merger or other
forced buyout of any of the stockholders by the other two (or to provide
certain protections in that event).
Valuations and Offers to Purchase Prior to a Squeeze-Out
The company’s credibility was damaged by its several offers to purchase
the petitioner’s stock at prices, in each instance, significantly below
the value of the petitioner’s shares indicated by third-party valuations
the company had received.
Key Practice Point for
Bankers Relating to DCF Analysis
No Liquidity Discount to Cost of Capital Size Premium
In AutoInfo, the court indicated that, in a DCF analysis for appraisal
purposes, the weighted average capital cost (WACC) component of the
capital asset pricing model (CAPM) should generally be calculated without
applying any “marketability” or “illiquidity” discount to the equity size
premium derived from the Ibbotson tables. The court indicated agreement
with the position, taken in Gearreald v. JustCare (2012), that, as “the
‘liquidity effect’ contained within the size premium” relates to the
company’s ability to obtain capital at a certain cost, it is therefore
related to the company’s intrinsic value as a going concern, and should
therefore be included in the calculation of its cost of capital in a DCF
analysis for appraisal purposes.
Hypothetical Corporate-Level Tax Rate for Subchapter S Corporation
According to the court in Cannon, determining the corporate-level tax rate
to calculate the company’s projected free cash flows, a hypothetical rate
must be determined for an S corporation that “treats the S corporation
shareholder ... as receiving the full benefit of untaxed dividends, by
equating [his] after-tax return to the after-dividend return to a C
shareholder.”
—By Steven Epstein, Arthur Fleischer Jr., Peter S. Golden, Brian T.
Mangino, Philip Richter, Robert C. Schwenkel, John E. Sorkin and Gail
Weinstein,
Fried Frank Harris Shriver & Jacobson LLP
Steven Epstein,
Peter Golden,
Philip Richter,
Robert Schwenkel and
John Sorkin are partners in Fried
Frank's New York office.
Brian Mangino is a partner in
Washington, D.C.
Arthur Fleischer and
Gail Weinstein are senior counsel in
New York.
The opinions expressed are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily
reflect the views of the firm, its clients, or Portfolio Media Inc., or
any of its or their respective affiliates. This article is for general
information purposes and is not intended to be and should not be taken as
legal advice.
© 2015, Portfolio Media, Inc. |
|
|