23
October 2014
Shareholder Value Maximization: The World’s Dumbest Idea?
By
Usman Hayat, CFA
If
you agree with the economist John Maynard Keynes that “ideas shape the
course of history,” then you ought to agree that the history of modern
business and finance has been shaped by one influential idea: that the
job of a company’s management is to maximize shareholder value. But
according to
James Montier,
a distinguished investment professional and behavioural finance
writer, shareholder value maximization is “a bad idea.” He believes
it has not added any value for shareholders and has contributed to
such major economic and social problems as short-termism and rising
inequality.
Montier made his case against shareholder value maximization when
delivering the closing keynote address at the
2014 European
Investment Conference
in London, a video of which can be viewed below. In his characteristic
iconoclastic style with a generous use of ironic humour, Montier
labeled shareholder value maximization, the way Jack Welch, the former
CEO of GE, had once described it in 2009, as “the
dumbest idea in the world.”
An Academic Opinion without Much Evidence
Montier said that the idea of shareholder value maximization didn’t
come from businesses but rather originated as an opinion in academia
and was unsupported by much evidence. It is most directly traced to
an op-ed written by
economist Milton Friedman in
1970. Over the years, academic research papers on the subject, such as
those by Michael
C. Jensen and William H. Meckling (PDF) and
Jensen and Kevin J.
Murphy (PDF),
have made it inseparable from the alignment of incentives. That is,
top management of companies should be offered financial incentives
(e.g., stock ownership and call options) to align their interest with
maximizing the stock price.
The
idea of shareholder value and incentives then worked its way into
practice. Montier gave the example of
Business Roundtable
(BRT), an association of CEOs of major US companies. He said that in
1981, the mission of BRT referred to making quality goods and
services, earning a profit, and building the economy, but by 1997, it
became firmly focused on shareholder value.
Failing Shareholders
Montier claimed that shareholder value maximization has failed the
shareholders — its intended beneficiaries. Despite enormous increases
in compensation of CEOs and a rising proportion of financial
incentives through stock ownership and options, shareholders are not
better off. To illustrate this point with a case example, Montier
compared the return performance of IBM, which switched its focus to
shareholder value maximization, to that of Johnson & Johnson, which
retained
its credo (PDF)
emphasizing responsibility to customers, employees, and communities.
Montier showed that during 1971–2013, the stock of Johnson & Johnson
had indeed outperformed that of IBM.
Widening his analysis, Montier asserted that during 1940–1990, what he
called “the managerial era,” the annual real return to shareholders in
listed equities was 7%. After the 1990s, during “the shareholder value
maximization era,” it was also about 7%. But, he added, when adjusted
for changes in valuation independent of shareholder value
maximization, isolating yield and growth, the return in the
shareholder value maximization era lags by about 2 percentage points.
What Went Wrong?
Montier said that financial incentives for management that were meant
to maximize shareholder value did not work because of a flawed
understanding of how human beings respond to incentives. Under the
mantra of shareholder value maximization, CEOs are now being paid more
than ever before and about two-thirds of that compensation is in the
form of stock ownership and stock options. Call options, which only
pay off if stock prices rise, encourage short-term gaming by CEOs
rather than long-term value creation. More importantly,
as research from
behavioural finance shows,
when incentives become large, those being incentivized become obsessed
with the incentives themselves and lose sight of what the incentives
are meant to achieve. Montier believes that rather than focusing on
the long-term prosperity of their businesses, CEOs are focusing on how
much more money they can make if they can game the system.
Instead of observing reality and deducing their theories from what
they see, Montier claimed, economists supporting shareholder value
maximization tried to fit available facts to their opinions about
incentives and human behaviour. Montier quoted President Ronald
Reagan: “An economist is someone who sees something happen in practice
and wonders if it’d work in theory.”
A
Cause of Short-Termism and Inequality
Montier contended that shareholder value maximization and financial
incentives are a direct cause of short-termism and inequality. The
life-span of an S&P 500 company has decreased from more than 26 years
in 1971–1976 to close to 15 years in 2005–2010, and the average tenure
of CEOs has shrunk from 10 years to six years. Private companies, not
subject to the same short-termism pressures,
invest more than
public companies,
and CFOs of listed companies are
willing to forego
projects with positive net present value to make quarterly earnings
targets.
From “retain and reinvest,” companies have moved to “downsize
and distribute.”
It is hard to argue that companies do not have ample investment
opportunities available to them in the real economy, but many
companies are instead buying back shares, often at record high prices.
Connecting short-termism with its effects on society and economy,
Montier pointed to “three stylized facts”:
1. Business
investment as a percentage of GDP is declining.
2. There
is rising income inequality in society (PDF),
and the share of income of business executives and financiers has
increased dramatically.
3. Labor
is losing its share of GDP.
Short-termism and inequality hurt our societies and economies, Montier
said. There are fewer new projects and jobs because companies are
preoccupied with meeting quarterly earnings targets. There is also
less spending in the economy, slowing down our economic growth, as
those who spend a higher proportion of their income have a lower share
of income.
Montier believes that our world would have looked different if instead
of maximizing shareholder value and enriching themselves
with exorbitant and problematic incentives, those managing companies
were required to focus on running their businesses, producing quality
goods and services, treating customers and workers fairly, and
creating shareholder value as a by-product, not as an
objective.
video
|