Posted by R. Christopher
Small, Co-editor, HLS Forum on Corporate Governance and Financial
Regulation, on Monday February 9, 2015 at
9:00 am
Editor’s Note: The following post comes to us
from
Alon Brav, Professor of Finance at Duke University;
Amil Dasgupta of the Department of Finance at the London
School of Economics; and
Richmond Mathews of the Department of Finance at the
University of Maryland. |
In our paper
Wolf Pack Activism, which was recently made publicly available on
SSRN, we provide a model analyzing a prominent and controversial
governance tactic used by activist hedge funds. The tactic involves
multiple hedge funds or other activist investors congregating around a
target, with one acting as a “lead” activist and others as peripheral
activists. This has been colorfully dubbed the “wolf pack” tactic by
market observers. The use of wolf packs has intensified in recent
years and has attracted a great deal of attention. Indeed, a recent
post on this forum described 2014 as “the year of the wolf pack”.
The formation of a wolf pack
may enable activist hedge funds to gain the significant influence that
they appear to wield in target firms with relatively small holdings:
According to
recent research, the median stake of activist hedge funds at the
initiation of an activist campaign is only 6.3%. Yet, the process by
which a wolf pack form appears to be subtle, for at least two reasons.
First, wolf pack activity appears to be ostensibly uncoordinated—i.e.,
no formal coalition is formed—a fact that is usually attributed to an
attempt by the funds to circumvent the requirement for group filing
under Regulation 13D when governance activities are coalitional (e.g.,
Briggs 2006). Second, wolf packs appear to form dynamically:
Writing in this forum in 2009,
Nathan describes the process of wolf pack formation as follows:
“The market’s knowledge of the formation of a wolf pack (either
through word of mouth or public announcement of a destabilization
campaign by the lead wolf pack member) often leads to additional
activist funds entering the fray against the target corporation,
resulting in a rapid (and often outcome determinative) change in
composition of the target’s shareholder base seemingly overnight.”
The subtle nature of wolf
pack formation, combined with the prominence of this tactic, raises
some questions of key importance to corporate governance: How can
formally uncoordinated dynamic wolf pack activity work? What role does
the lead activist play? What is the role of the peripheral wolf pack
members? How do leaders and followers influence each other?
Our model addresses these
questions. We consider multiple activists of different sizes: One
large and many small. There is one lead activist who is as large as
several small activists taken together and is better informed than the
small activists. Our model involves two key components. The first
component is a static model of “engagement” by activist investors,
which may be interpreted to include talking with target management,
making public statements, sponsoring and voting on proxy proposals
etc. Successful engagement naturally involves a collective action
problem: Engagement can only succeed if there is enough pressure on
management, given the underlying fundamentals of the firm. To capture
this collective action problem, we build on methodology for analyzing
asymmetric coordination problems in
Corsetti, Dasgupta, Morris, and Shin (2004). The second component
is a dynamic model of block-building which anticipates the subsequent
engagement process. A key aspect of our analysis is that the ownership
structure of the target firm (the total activist stake and the
size-distribution of activists) is endogenous and determines the
success of activism, given firm fundamentals.
We first show that the
concentration of skill and capital matters: holding constant total
activist ownership, the presence of a lead activist improves the
coordination of wolf pack members in the engagement game, leading to a
higher probability of successful activism. This occurs solely because
the lead activist’s presence implicitly helps the smaller
activists to coordinate their efforts and become more aggressive at
engaging the target, since in our model there is no overt
communication among the activists and they all act simultaneously. An
implication of this result is that, even when a significant number of
shares are held by potential activists, the arrival of a “lead”
activist who holds a larger block may be a necessary catalyst for a
successful campaign, which is consistent with the activist strategies
that are well documented in the empirical literature.
We next show the beneficial
effect of the presence of small activists on a lead activist’s
decision to buy shares in the target. In particular, the larger is the
wolf pack of small activists the lead activist can expect to exist at
the time of the campaign, the more likely it is that buying a stake
will be profitable given the activist’s opportunity cost of tying up
capital. Importantly, the expected wolf pack size consists of both
small activists that already own stakes, and those that can be
expected to purchase a stake after observing the lead activist’s
purchase decision.
We also examine the dynamics
of optimal purchase decisions by small activists. We find that the
acquisition of a position by the large activist (in effect, a 13D
filing) precipitates the immediate entry of a significant additional
number of small activists. While these activists know about the
potential for activism at the firm before the lead activist buys in,
other attractive uses of funds keep them from committing capital to
the firm before they are sure that a lead activist will emerge. Others
with lower opportunity costs may be willing to buy in earlier, as the
real (but smaller) chance of successful engagement in the absence of a
lead activist provides sufficient potential returns. Thus, our model
predicts that late entrants to activism will be those who have
relatively higher opportunity costs of tying up capital. One potential
way to interpret this is that more concentrated, smaller, and more
“specialized” vehicles (such as other activist funds) may be more
inclined to acquire a stake only after the filing of a 13D by a lead
activist.
The full paper is available
for download
here.
All copyright and trademarks in content on this site are owned by
their respective owners. Other content © 2015 The President and
Fellows of Harvard College. |
|