Mutual Fund Transparency and Corporate
Myopia
Posted by Vikas Agarwal (Georgia State
University), Rahul Vashishtha (Duke University), and Mohan
Venkatachalam (Duke University), on Wednesday, July 11, 2018
Editor’s Note:
Vikas Agarwal is H. Talmage Dobbs, Jr. Chair and Professor of
Finance at Georgia State University J. Mack Robinson College of
Business; Rahul Vashishtha
is Associate Professor of Accounting at Duke University Fuqua
School of Business; and Mohan Venkatachalam is R.J. Reynolds
Professor of Accounting at Duke University Fuqua School of
Business; This post is based on their recent
article, forthcoming in the Review of Financial Studies.
Related research from the Program on Corporate Governance
includes The
Agency Problems of Institutional Investors by
Lucian Bebchuk, Alma Cohen, and Scott Hirst (discussed on the
Forum
here). |
Much anecdotal and large-sample evidence suggests
that pressure from institutional investors to report good short-run financial
performance can hinder investment in innovative projects that hurt short-term
profits but generate value in the long run. But what incentivizes institutional
investors to put excessive focus on short-run results? In
Mutual Fund Transparency and Corporate Myopia (Review of Financial
Studies, 2018, 31(5), pp. 1966-2003), we explore the role of mandated
frequent disclosures of portfolio holdings by mutual fund managers in shaping
their emphasis on short-term corporate performance and the concomitant myopic
underinvestment in innovative activities by investee firms’ managers.
Our focus on
the mutual fund portfolio disclosures is motivated by prior work that
argues that fund managers’ short-term focus stems from their career
concerns (e.g., Shleifer and Vishny, 1990)
and greater transparency about their actions (i.e., portfolio
choices) can amplify these concerns (e.g., Prat, 2005).
Intuitively, the idea is that fund managers are concerned
about their own performance measurement, which is used by fund
investors to make inferences about fund managers’ stock picking
abilities. Suppose a fund manager invests in a firm that is making
significant R&D investments that will only payoff in the long run and
has so far shown poor short-term earnings and stock price performance.
Such a fund manager runs the risk that fund investors may attribute
poor short-term performance of the investee firm to poor stock
selection ability, resulting in fund outflows and job termination.
Thus, career concerns reduce fund managers’ willingness to “ride-out”
the declines in short-term performance of investee firms.
Prat (2005) shows that
tighter monitoring of fund managers’ portfolio choices can amplify career
concerns and their short-term focus. The intuition is that the agents (fund
managers) are aware that the principals (fund investors) are closely
scrutinizing their actions. This incentivizes the agents to take actions that
are perceived as high-ability actions even if the agent’s private information
suggests that some other action is optimal. Thus, as fund investors gain access
to more frequent and reliable information on fund managers’ stock picks, fund
managers may excessively focus on holding stocks that appear as “winners” in
these short-term disclosures. Consequently, frequent portfolio disclosures can
reduce the fund manager’s tolerance for having investee firms in the portfolio
that pursue policies that will generate value in the long run, but can appear as
“poor” stock picks in short-term portfolio disclosures. This increased
short-term focus of fund managers can create pressure on managers of investee
firms to behave myopically.
Considerable anecdotal
evidence exists in support of the above arguments. The following quote from a
money manager in Lakonishok et al. (1991) directly highlights how the intense
pressure to show winning stocks in their quarterly portfolio disclosures can
cause money managers to myopically ignore the future potential of some stocks:
“Nobody wants to be caught showing last quarter’s disasters. … You throw out
the duds because you don’t want to have to apologize for and defend a stock’s
presence to clients even though your investment judgment may be to hold.”
We use the securities
market regulation in 2004 that altered the disclosure frequency of portfolio
holdings by mutual fund managers from semi-annual to quarterly reporting to
investigate whether institutional investors can pressurize the corporate
managers to behave myopically. Using a difference-in-differences design, we find
strong evidence of a decline in corporate innovation (as measured by
citation-weighted patent counts) following the regulation, for firms with high
ownership by mutual funds that were forced to increase the frequency of
portfolio disclosures subsequent to the regulation. The innovation decline is
much greater when bulk of the ownership comes from more career concerned younger
fund managers who would have greater incentives to signal their ability by
appearing to make smart portfolio choices. We also uncover direct evidence of
increased short-term focus in fund managers’ trading behavior, which exhibits
shorter holding periods, increased sensitivity of holdings to short-term
investee firm performance, and reduced portfolio allocation toward innovative
firms following the regulation.
These results highlight
the role of mandated quarterly portfolio disclosures in shaping short-term
incentives and lend support to the argument in Shleifer and Vishny (1990) that
it is the money managers’ own career concerns and performance evaluation
pressures that lie at the root of their short-term focus that promotes corporate
myopic behavior. This study also adds to our understanding of the consequences
of increased mandated information disclosure by establishing how it can create
adverse real effects by distorting the incentives of career-concerned agents.
Finally, the study portrays a dark side of the consequences of the agency
relation between money managers and fund investors on the real economy, a
phenomenon that has become increasingly important to understand because of the
astounding growth in delegated money management over the last three decades.
The complete paper is
available for download
here.
Endnotes
1
Shleifer, A., and R. W. Vishny, 1990, Equilibrium short horizons of
investors and firms, American Economic Review 80, 148‒153.(go
back)
2
Prat, A., 2005, The wrong kind of transparency, American Economic Review,
95(3), 862‒877.(go
back)
3
Lakonishok, J., A. Shleifer, R. Thaler, and R. Vishny, 1991, Window
dressing by pension fund managers, American Economic Review 81, 227‒231.(go
back)
Harvard Law School Forum
on Corporate Governance and Financial Regulation
All copyright and trademarks in content on this site are owned by
their respective owners. Other content © 2018 The President and
Fellows of Harvard College. |