Index Funds and the Future of Corporate
Governance: Theory, Evidence, and Policy
Posted by Lucian Bebchuk (Harvard Law
School) and Scott Hirst (Boston University), on Wednesday, November
28, 2018
Editor’s Note:
Lucian Bebchuk is the James Barr Ames Professor of Law,
Economics, and Finance, and Director of the Program on Corporate
Governance, at Harvard Law School.
Scott Hirst is Associate Professor at Boston University School
of Law and Director of Institutional Investor Research at the
Harvard Law School Program on Corporate Governance. This post is
based on their recent
study. Related research from the Program on Corporate
Governance includes
The Agency Problems of Institutional Investors by Lucian
Bebchuk, Alma Cohen, and Scott Hirst (discussed on the Forum
here). |
Index funds own an increasingly large proportion of
American public companies, currently more than one fifth and steadily growing.
Understanding the stewardship decisions of index fund managers—how they monitor,
vote, and engage with their portfolio companies—is critical for corporate law
scholarship. In a study that we recently placed on SSRN—Index
Funds and the Future of Corporate Governance: Theory, Evidence and Policy—we
seek to contribute to such understanding by providing a comprehensive
theoretical, empirical, and policy analysis of index fund stewardship.
We begin by putting forward an
agency-costs theory of index fund incentives. Stewardship decisions by
index funds depend not just on the interests of index fund investors
but also the incentives of index fund managers. Our agency-costs
analysis shows that index funds have strong incentives to (i)
under-invest in stewardship, and (ii) defer excessively to the
preferences and positions of corporate managers.
We then
provide the first comprehensive and detailed evidence of the full range of
stewardship activities that index funds do and do not undertake. This body of
evidence, we show, is inconsistent with a no-agency-costs view but can be
explained by our agency-cost analysis.
We next
put forward a set of policy reforms that should be considered in order to
encourage index funds to invest in stewardship, to reduce their incentives to be
deferential to corporate managers, and to address the concentration of power in
the hands of the largest index fund managers. Finally, we discuss how our
analysis should reorient important ongoing debates regarding common ownership
and hedge fund activism.
The
policy measures we put forward, and the beneficial role of hedge fund activism,
can partly but not fully address the incentive problems that we analyze and
document. These problems are expected to remain a significant aspect of the
corporate governance landscape, and should be the subject of close attention by
policymakers, market participants, and scholars.
Below
is a more detailed account of our study:
Index
funds—investment funds that mechanically track the performance of an index—hold
an increasingly large proportion of the equity of U.S. public companies. The
sector is dominated by three index fund managers—BlackRock, State Street Global
Advisors (SSGA), and Vanguard, often referred to as the “Big Three”. The Big
Three manage over $5 trillion of U.S. corporate equities, collectively vote
about 20% of the shares in all S&P 500 companies, and each holds a position of
5% or more in a vast number of companies. The proportion of assets in index
funds has risen dramatically over the past two decades, reaching more than 20%
in 2017, and is expected to continue growing substantially over the next decade.
The
large and steadily growing share of corporate equities held by index funds, and
especially the Big Three, has transformed ownership patterns in the U.S. public
market. It has also been attracting increasing attention to index fund
stewardship.
Leaders
of the Big Three have repeatedly stressed the importance of responsible
stewardship, and their strong commitment to it. For example, Vanguard’s then-CEO
William McNabb stated that “We care deeply about governance”, and that
“Vanguard’s vote and our voice on governance are the most important levers we
have to protect our clients’ investments.” Similarly, BlackRock’s CEO Larry Fink
stated that “our responsibility to engage and vote is more important than ever”
and that “the growth of indexing demands that we now take this function to a new
level.” The Chief Investment Officer (CIO) of SSGA stated that “SSGA’s asset
stewardship program continues to be foundational to our mission.”
The Big
Three leaders have also stated both their willingness to devote the necessary
resources to stewardship, and their belief in the governance benefits that their
investments produce. For example, Vanguard’s McNabb has said, of governance,
that “We’re good at it. Vanguard’s Investment Stewardship program is vibrant and
growing.” Similarly, BlackRock’s Fink has stated that BlackRock “intends to
double the size of [its] investment stewardship team over the next three years.
The growth of [BlackRock’s] team will help foster even more effective
engagement.”
The
stewardship promise of index funds arises from their large stakes and their
long-term commitment to the companies in which they invest. Their large stakes
provide these funds with significant potential influence, and imply that by
improving the value of their portfolio companies they can help bring about
significant gains for their portfolios. Furthermore, because index funds have no
“exit” from their positions in portfolio companies as long as the companies
remain in the index, they have a long-term perspective, and are not tempted by
short-term gains at the expense of long-term value. This long-term perspective
has been stressed by Big Three leaders, and applauded by commentators.
Vanguard’s founder, the current elder statesman of index investing, has said
that “index funds are the … best hope for corporate governance.”
Will
index funds deliver on this promise? Do any significant impediments stand in the
way? How do the legal rules and policies affect index fund stewardship? Given
the dominant and growing role that index funds play in the capital markets,
these questions are of first-order importance, and are the focus of our Article.
In
particular, we seek to make three contributions. First, we provide an analytical
framework for understanding the incentives of index fund managers. Our analysis
demonstrates that index funds managers have strong incentives to (i)
under-invest in stewardship and (ii) defer excessively to the preferences and
positions of corporate managers.
Our
second contribution is to provide the first comprehensive evidence of the full
range of stewardship choices made by index fund managers, especially the Big
Three. We find that this evidence is, on the whole, consistent with the
incentive problems that our analytical framework identifies. The evidence thus
reinforces the concerns suggested by this framework.
Our
third contribution is to explore the policy implications of the incentive
problems of index fund managers that we identify and document. We put forward a
number of policy measures to address these incentive problems. These measures
should be considered to improve index fund stewardship—and thereby, the
governance and performance of public companies. We also explain how these
incentive problems shed light on important ongoing debates about common
ownership and hedge funds.
Our
analysis is organized as follows. Part I discusses the features of index funds
that have given rise to high hopes for index fund stewardship. The views of Big
Three leaders and supporters of index fund stewardship, we explain, are premised
on a belief that index fund decisions can be largely understood as being focused
on maximizing the long-term value of their investment portfolios, and that
agency problems are not a key driver of those decisions.
By
contrast to this “no-agency-costs” view, Part II puts forward an alternative
“agency-costs” view. Stewardship decisions for an index fund are not made by the
index fund’s own beneficial investors, which we refer to as the “index fund
investors,” but rather by its investment adviser, which we label the “index fund
manager.” As a result, the incentives of index fund managers are critical. We
identify two types of incentive problems that push the stewardship decisions of
index fund managers away from those that would best serve the interests of index
fund investors.
Incentives to Under-Invest in Stewardship. Stewardship that increases the
value of portfolio companies will benefit index fund investors. However, index
fund managers are remunerated with a very small percentage of their assets under
management (AUM) and thus would capture a correspondingly small fraction of such
increases in value. They therefore have much more limited incentives to invest
in stewardship than their beneficial investors would prefer. Furthermore, if
stewardship by an index fund manager increases the value of a portfolio company,
rival index funds that track the same index (and investors in those funds) will
receive the benefit of the increase in value without any expenditure of their
own. As a result, an interest in improving financial performance relative to
rival index fund managers does not provide any incentive to invest in
stewardship. Furthermore, we explain that competition with actively managed
funds cannot be expected to address the substantial incentives to under-invest
in stewardship that we identify.
Incentives to be Excessively Deferential. When index fund managers face
qualitative stewardship decisions, we show that they have incentives to be
excessively deferential—relative to what would best serve the interests of their
own beneficial investors—toward the preferences and positions of the managers of
portfolio companies. This is because the choice between deference to managers
and nondeference not only affects the value of the index fund’s portfolio, but
could also affect the private interests of the index fund manager.
We then
identify and analyze three significant ways in which index fund managers could
well benefit privately from such deference. First, we show that existing or
potential business relationships between index fund managers and their portfolio
companies give the index fund managers incentives to adopt principles, policies,
and practices that defer to corporate managers. Second, we explain that, in the
many companies where the Big Three have positions of 5% or more of the company’s
stock, taking certain nondeferential actions would trigger obligations that
would impose substantial additional costs on the index fund manager. Finally,
and importantly, the growing power of the Big Three means that a nondeferential
approach would likely encounter significant resistance from corporate managers,
which would create a significant risk of regulatory backlash.
We
focus on understanding the structural incentive problems that motivate index
fund managers to under-invest in stewardship and defer to corporate managers,
thereby impeding their ability to deliver on their governance promise. We stress
that in some cases, fiduciary norms, or a desire to do the right thing, could
lead well-meaning index fund managers to take actions that differ from those
suggested by a pure incentive analysis. Furthermore, index fund managers also
have incentives to be perceived as responsible stewards by their beneficial
investors and by the public—and thus, to avoid actions that would make salient
their under-investing in stewardship and deferring to corporate managers. These
factors could well constrain the force of the problems that we investigate.
However, these structural problems should be expected to have significant
effects; the evidence we present in Part III demonstrates that this is, in
fact, the case.
As with
any other economic theory, the test for whether the no-agency-costs view or the
agency-costs view are valid is the extent to which they are consistent with and
can explain the extant evidence. Part III therefore puts forward evidence on
the actual stewardship activities that the Big Three index funds do and do not
undertake. We combine hand-collected data and data from various public sources
to piece together a broad and detailed picture of index fund stewardship. In
particular, we investigate eight dimensions of stewardship:
1.
Actual Stewardship Investments. Our analysis provides estimates of the
stewardship personnel, both in terms of workdays and dollar cost, devoted to
particular companies. Whereas supporters of index fund stewardship have focused
on recent increases in stewardship staff of the Big Three, our analysis examines
personnel resources in the context of the Big Three’s assets under management
and their number of portfolio companies. We show that the Big Three devote an
economically negligible fraction of their fee income to stewardship, and that
their stewardship staffing enables only limited and cursory stewardship for the
vast majority of their portfolio companies.
2.
Behind-the-Scenes Engagements. Supporters of index fund stewardship view
private engagements by the Big Three as explaining why they refrain from using
certain other stewardship tools available to shareholders. However, we show that
the Big Three engage with a very small proportion of their portfolio companies,
and only a small proportion of these engagements involve more than a single
conversation. Furthermore, refraining from using other stewardship tools also
has an adverse effect on the small minority of cases in which private
engagements do occur. The Big Three’s private engagement thus cannot constitute
an adequate substitute for the use of other stewardship tools.
3.
Limited Attention to Performance. Our analysis of the voting guidelines and
stewardship reports of the Big Three indicates that their stewardship focuses on
governance structures and processes and pays limited attention to financial
underperformance. While portfolio company compliance with governance best
practices serves the interests of index funds investors, those investors would
also benefit substantially from stewardship aimed at identifying, addressing,
and remedying financial underperformance.
4.
Pro-Management Voting. We examine data on votes cast by the Big Three on
matters of central importance to managers, such as executive compensation and
proxy contests with activist hedge funds. We show that the Big Three’s votes on
these matters reveals considerable deference to corporate managers. For example,
the Big Three very rarely oppose corporate managers in say-on-pay votes, and are
less likely than other investors to oppose managers in proxy fights against
activists.
5.
Avoiding Shareholder Proposals. Shareholder proposals have proven to be an
effective stewardship tool for bringing about governance changes at broad groups
of public companies. Many of the Big Three’s portfolio companies persistently
fail to adopt the best governance practices that the Big Three support. Given
these failures, and the Big Three’s focus on governance processes, it would be
natural for the Big Three to submit shareholder proposals to such companies
aimed at addressing such failures. However, our examination of shareholder
proposals over the last decade indicates that the Big Three have completely
refrained from submitting such proposals.
6.
Avoiding Engagement Regarding Companies’ Nomination of Directors. Index
fund investors could well benefit if index fund managers communicated with the
boards of underperforming companies about replacing or adding certain directors.
However, our examination of director nominations and Schedule 13D filings over
the past decade indicates that the Big Three have refrained from such
engagements.
7.
Limited Involvement in Governance Reforms. Index fund investors would
benefit from involvement by index fund managers in corporate governance
reforms—such as supporting desirable changes and opposing undesirable
changes—that could materially affect the value of many portfolio companies. We
therefore review all of the comments submitted on proposed rulemaking regarding
corporate governance issues by the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), and
the filing of amicus briefs in precedential litigation. We find that the Big
Three have contributed very few such comments and no amicus briefs over the past
decade, and were much less involved in such reforms than asset owners with much
smaller portfolios.
8.
Lead Plaintiff Positions. Legal rules encourage institutional investors
with “skin in the game” to take on lead plaintiff positions in securities class
actions; this serves the interests of their investors by monitoring class
counsel, settlement agreements and recoveries, and the terms of governance
reforms incorporated in such settlements. We therefore examine the lead
plaintiffs selected in the large set of significant class actions over the past
decade. Although the Big Three’s investors often have significant skin in the
game, we find that the Big Three refrained from taking on lead plaintiff
positions in any of these cases.
Taken
together, the body of evidence that we document is difficult to reconcile with a
“no-agency-cost” view under which stewardship choices are made to maximize the
value of managed portfolios. Rather, the evidence is, on the whole, consistent
with, and can be explained by, the agency-costs view and its incentive analysis
described in Part II.
In the
course of examining the evidence on index fund stewardship, we consider the
argument that some types of stewardship activities are outside the “business
model” of the Big Three. This argument raises the question of why this
is the case. The “business models” of the Big Three and the stewardship
activities they choose to undertake are not exogenous; rather, they are a
product of choices made by index fund managers, and thus they follow from the
incentives we analyze.
In Part
IV we consider the policy implications of our theory and evidence. We begin by
examining several approaches to address the incentives of index fund managers to
under-invest in stewardship and defer excessively to corporate managers. In
particular, we consider measures to encourage stewardship investments, as well
as to address the distortions arising from business ties between index fund
managers and public companies. We also examine measures to bring transparency to
the private engagements conducted by index fund managers and their portfolio
companies—transparency that, we argue, is necessary to provide material
information to investors, and can provide beneficial incentives to those engaged
in such engagements.
We
further discuss placing limits on the fraction of equity of any public company
that could be managed by a single index fund manager. The expectation that the
proportion of corporate equities held by index funds will keep rising makes it
especially important to consider the desirability of continuing the Big Three’s
dominance. For instance, we explain that if the index fund sector continues to
grow and index fund managers control 45% of corporate equity, having a “Giant
Three” each holding 15% would be inferior to having a “Big-ish Nine” each
holding 5%.
Part
IV also discusses the significant implications of our analysis for two
important ongoing debates. One such debate concerns influential claims that the
rise in common ownership patterns—whereby institutional investors hold shares in
many companies in the same sector—can be expected to have anticompetitive
effects and should be a focus of antitrust regulators. Our analysis indicates
that these claims are not warranted. The second debate concerns activist hedge
funds. Our analysis undermines claims by opponents of hedge fund activism that
index fund stewardship is superior to—and should replace—hedge fund activism. We
show that, to the contrary, the incentive problems of index fund managers that
we identify and analyze make the role of activist hedge funds especially
important.
Although the policy measures we put forward would improve matters, they should
not be expected to eliminate the incentive problems that we identify. Similarly,
although activist hedge funds make up for some of the shortcomings of index fund
stewardship, we explain that they do not and cannot fully address these
shortcomings. The problems that we identify and document can be expected to
remain an important element of the corporate governance landscape. Obtaining a
clear understanding of these problems—to which this this Article seeks to
contribute—is critical for policy makers and market participants.
Our
study is available
here. Comments would be most welcome.
Harvard Law School Forum
on Corporate Governance and Financial Regulation
All copyright and trademarks in content on this site are owned by
their respective owners. Other content © 2018 The President and
Fellows of Harvard College. |