Soft Shareholder Activism
Posted by Doron Levit (University of
Pennsylvania), on Wednesday, December 19, 2018
Editor’s Note:
Doron Levit is Assistant Professor of Finance at The Wharton
School of the University of Pennsylvania. This post is based on a
recent article by
Professor Levit, forthcoming in the Review of Financial
Studies. Related research from the Program on Corporate
Governance includes
Dancing with Activists by Lucian Bebchuk, Alon Brav, Wei Jiang,
and Thomas Keusch (discussed on the Forum
here). |
The modus operandi of a typical activist investor is
to target a public company and propose major changes to its strategy, financial
policy, operations, and personal. To defend themselves against these proposals,
companies use poison pills, staggered boards, dual-class structures, and other
measures. Securities regulation and disclosure requirements also limit the power
of activists. In practice, activists rarely own a controlling stake. Without
control, activist investors cannot force their ideas on their target companies;
they must persuade its board of directors or the majority of shareholders that
adopting their proposals is in the best interests of the firm. Simply put,
shareholder activism requires communication and persuasion.
Consistent
with this idea, recent evidence suggests that behind-the-scenes
communications between investors and firms is an important corporate
governance mechanism, perhaps more important than previously thought
(e.g., McCahery et al. 2016). This evidence raises two fundamental
questions that have been overlooked by the existing literature. First,
what factors contribute to successful dialogues between investors and
firms? Second, under what circumstances will investors resort to more
aggressive tactics, and when will they choose to exit?
My article Soft
Shareholder Activism, which is forthcoming in the Review of Financial
Studies, investigates the conditions under which communications between
investors and firms is an effective form of shareholder activism. I develop a
model in which the activist can communicate (cheap-talk) with the board of the
target company, and depending on the reaction to her demand, the activist can
either launch a public campaign (i.e., employing a “voice” mechanism) or exit
her position. The innovation of the model is the introduction of the possibility
of direct communications between investors and firms into a framework with voice
and exit, the “traditional” governance mechanisms. Moreover, different from the
existing literature, the activist in my model cannot force her ideas on the
company; she must either persuade the board to adopt her proposal, or persuade
other shareholders to support her campaign. My model emphasizes this important
but often neglected aspect of shareholder activism, and as such, offers a new
perspective to this important literature.
The challenge of the
activist in this model is to convince the board, who is biased and uninformed,
to change the status quo of the firm (e.g., spinning off a division). At
equilibrium, the board accommodates the activist’s demand either because it is
persuaded by her arguments that changing the status quo is in the best interests
of the firm or out of fear that the activist will launch a successful public
campaign if her demand is ignored. Communication is effective if the activist
can use her private information to influence the board’s decision at
equilibrium.
My analysis
demonstrates that the threat of voice facilitates communication since the most
effective way directors can avoid the adverse consequences of a public campaign
is by accommodating the activist’s demand. In turn, the expected accommodation
of the board increases the incentive of the activist to engage and communicate
in the first place. Generally, an activist’s threat is more credible when
rallying support from other shareholders is easier (e.g., shareholder base is
undispersed), control is contestable (e.g., declassified board, one class of
shares, no supermajority provisions), or the reputational and monetary damage to
the incumbent directors from a successful campaign is severe. The model predicts
that these factors would contribute to more effective communications. Moreover,
the analysis suggests that a public campaign is a sign of ineffective
behind-the-scenes communications, and vice a versa. Importantly, it implies that
factors that predict high frequency of public campaigns would in fact suggest
that the employed tactics are not effective enough to induce boards to comply
with demands that activists make behind closed-doors. Without explicitly
accounting for the possibility of unobserved communications, an empiricist might
reach the wrong conclusions.
The effect of exit on
communication is more nuanced. On one hand, the temptation of an activist to
“cut and run” harms the credibility of her threat to launch a public campaign if
her demand is ignored. Therefore, exit has an indirect effect on communication,
through its negative effect on voice. On the other hand, the option to exit
increases the activist’s credibility through two related but novel channels.
First, with exit, the activist insists on changing the status quo only if the
benefit from doing so is also higher than what she expects to get from selling
her shares. As a result, the board is convinced that whenever the activist
demands a change, the benefit to shareholders must be very high. This effect
relaxes the tension between the activist and the board and thereby facilitates
communication. Second, exit can also increase the credibility of the activist’s
threat to launch a successful public campaign. Essentially, the option to exit
gives the activist an opportunity to “put her money where her mouth is” by
choosing not to exercise this option. Therefore, the activist has more
credibility vis-a-vis shareholders and the board, and communication is more
effective in equilibrium. These results highlight that exit can complement voice
and facilitate communication.
The analysis shows that
the trade-off between these opposing forces and the overall effect of exit on
communication is determined by the properties of the activist’s proposal and the
voice mechanism, which leads to novel empirical predictions on the factors that
contribute to successful dialogues between investors and firms. Specifically, if
voice is ineffective as a governance mechanism (e.g., the target company has a
dual class share, a controlling shareholder, or a staggered board and draconian
supermajority provisions) or if the activist’s proposal is risky relative to the
status quo (e.g., the target operates in an emerging industry and the proposal
is not a standard fix to its balance sheet or corporate governance), the cut and
run effect is dominated and exit facilitates communication. However, if voice is
effective and the activist’s proposal is relatively safe, the cut and run effect
dominates and exit hinders communication. In general, the effect of exit is more
pronounced when the stock is liquid, the short-term capital gains taxes are low,
anonymous trade is feasible, or adverse selection is mild. The model predicts
that these various factors will be associated with the frequency of successful
dialogues between investors and firms.
As a whole, my analysis
highlights the importance of communications between investors and firms as a
form of shareholder activism.
The complete article is
available
here.
Harvard Law School Forum
on Corporate Governance and Financial Regulation
All copyright and trademarks in content on this site are owned by
their respective owners. Other content © 2018 The President and
Fellows of Harvard College. |