Board 3.0: An Introduction
Posted by Ronald J. Gilson and Jeffrey N.
Gordon (Columbia Law School), on Tuesday, March 26, 2019
Editor’s Note:
Ronald J. Gilson is Stern Professor of Law and Business at
Columbia Law School and Meyers Professor of Law and Business
Emeritus at Stanford Law School, and
Jeffrey N. Gordon is Richard Paul Richman Professor of Law at
Columbia Law School. This post is based on their recent
article, forthcoming in The Business Lawyer. |
In
Board 3.0: An Introduction, we sketch the case for a new board
structure as an option for public company boards. The current board
model—Board 2.0 in our terms—had its genesis in Mel Eisenberg’s iconic
1976 book. Eisenberg framed the ideal board as one dominated by
part-time independent directors charged with monitoring management’s
performance. This would replace the Board 1.0 model of directors who
served as management’s advisors and whose response to disagreements
with management was to resign rather than act. Board 2.0, however,
goes only so far. The board remains dependent on management for
company-sourced information and thus is heavily reliant on stock
market prices as a measure of management performance. The result has
been a board model of thinly informed, under-resourced,
and boundedly motivated directors, attractive to management
because of the judicially provided cover that such a board can deliver
in fending off the four horsemen of the corporate apocalypse:
plaintiffs’ lawyers, regulators, raiders and activists.
Over time we have seen
a recurrent pattern of 2.0 style monitoring boards composed of talented people
that fail to effectively monitor. Nevertheless, when companies fall short in
monitoring management’s business acumen or compliance obligations, we have also
seen a recurrent response: place even greater demands on the very board whose
structural inadequacies gave rise to the monitoring failure, for example, the
Millennium accounting scandals that gave rise to Sarbanes-Oxley and the 2008
Financial Crisis that led to Dodd-Frank.
The particular business
problem that urgently calls out for a new board model is created by the
interaction of two developments: the dramatic shift towards majoritarian
institutional ownership of most large public companies and the rise of a new
form of financial intermediary, the activist hedge fund. The consequence is
that, to an unprecedented extent, even the largest public companies (and their
management teams) are subject to credible proxy contests by shareholder
activists objecting to management’s strategic vision or operational competence.
(We trace these developments in Ronald J. Gilson & Jeffrey N. Gordon,
The Agency Costs of Agency Capitalism: Activist Investors and the Revaluation of
Governance Rights, 113 Colum. L. Rev. 863 (2013).) On the present Board 2.0
model, directors are poorly situated to defend management against what is at
least a credible business counter-vision. The consequence is that institutional
investors may themselves resolve through their votes strategic disputes between
the activist and company management rather than defer to the board’s assessment
of the company’s existing strategy.
Our goal is to develop
a model of thickly informed, well-resourced, and highly motivated
directors who could credibly monitor managerial strategy and operational skill
in cases where this would be particularly valuable. Of particular current
interest, Board 3.0 directors where appropriate could help credibly defend
management against shareholder activist incursions when institutional investors
are challenged to determine whether company underperformance results from market
myopia or from management hyperopia. Similarly, such directors could find a
place in extremely complex enterprise, such as finance, where the time and
expertise demanded of successful directors are high and the costs of business or
regulatory failure are profound.
One inspiration for
Board 3.0 is found in private equity, in which the high-powered incentives of
the private equity sponsor have produced a different mode of board and director
engagement that seems associated with high value creation. Porting over private
equity governance features to the public company board offers a fresh starting
point. There is no reason to think that Board 2.0 is the “end of history” for
corporate governance. The world of private markets, venture capital and private
equity, have made effective use of alternative board models. We seek to bring
some of that governance experimentalism to public companies. The Board 3.0 model
may solve some of the serious information asymmetries posed by some public
companies: Full disclosure of strategic plans may deprive companies of first
mover advantages in competitive markets and, more generally, may put public
companies at competitive disadvantage to private companies. Yet markets cannot
give value to plans that are not yet revealed, which makes the firm vulnerable
to activist shareholder pressure and may push firms to second best strategies.
Board 3.0 can mediate this problem by generating credibility with the
institutional investors called upon to resolve activist challenges. Seeding
public company boards with the private equity characteristics of Board 3.0 also
may reduce the push for corner solutions, such as dual class common structures
or take-private transactions.
To be sure, Board 3.0
may not fit some companies’ businesses, and some controlling shareholders may
find the more extreme versions of leveraged control more attractive whether or
not they improve or reduce performance. But expanding available board models by
adding one that can provide more robust monitoring and enhanced market
credibility can help with the right kind of companies. The changing nature of
ownership and the increasing complexity of many businesses has rendered Board
2.0 less effective than Eisenberg had hoped. The porting of elements of private
equity portfolio company boards to public company boards can provide a
governance structure that matches the evolution of the current business
environment.
The complete article is
available for download
here.
Harvard Law School Forum
on Corporate Governance and Financial Regulation
All copyright and trademarks in content on this site are owned by
their respective owners. Other content © 2019 The President and
Fellows of Harvard College. |