|
THE VALUATION GAP. PHOTOGRAPHER: MATTHEW BUSCH/BLOOMBERG |
|
|
|
Matt Levine is a Bloomberg View
columnist writing about Wall Street and the financial world.
Levine was previously an editor of Dealbreaker. He has worked as
an investment banker at Goldman Sachs and a mergers and
acquisitions lawyer at Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz. He spent
a year clerking for the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Third
Circuit and taught high school Latin. Levine has a bachelor's
degree in classics from Harvard University and a law degree from
Yale Law School. He lives in New York.
|
Wall Street
Michael Dell Bought His Company Too Cheaply
JUNE 1, 2016 11:38 AM EDT
By
Matt Levine
If you own a stock that you think is worth $10 a share, and I also own
that stock and I think it's worth $20 a share, I can try to convince
you that I'm right. I can make predictions about the company's future
prospects and earnings, and build a discounted cash flow model to
prove that the stock really is worth $20. And you can make different
assumptions about the future, and build different models, and try to
convince me that $10 is the right number. But this is all kind of
dumb. I should just pay you $12 for your shares. Then you get paid
more than you think the stock is worth, and I get stock that I think
is worth more than I paid, and we never have to discuss it. This is
called the efficient markets hypothesis.[1]
This is such a
good and pleasant way of avoiding discussion that it is the
principal way that people in finance make arguments. Every once in
a while a famous investor will rent out a ballroom and give a
three-hour presentation about why a stock is going to go up (or down).
But these presentations are actually relatively rare. Mostly when
investors think a stock is going to go up, they buy the stock. The
buying is the argument. You don't even need a ballroom.
One argument
that you hear a lot is that public stock markets are too focused on
the short term, giving too much weight to quarterly results and not
enough to long-term visions. Structurally, this argument tends to be
expressed by the people with the long-term visions, who feel that
they're being undervalued.[2] They
make the argument in words, in shareholder letters and television
appearances, but they also sometimes make it with money. Companies
sometimes buy back their stock because their managers think the market
undervalues it. And companies that aren't already public perhaps
put off going public to avoid
all the short-termism, or, if they do go public, do it in ways that
insulate the managers from the
markets' short-term focus.
One person who thought his company's
stock was undervalued by a short-term public market is Michael Dell,
the founder and chief executive officer of Dell Inc., which in his
long-term vision was moving from being a personal-computer
manufacturer into an enterprise software company. He made this
argument in boring verbal ways:[3]
Mr. Dell
lamented that the market just "didn't get" the Company. He thought
that in spite of the Company‘s transformation, "Dell [was] still
seen as a PC business." Mr. Dell conferred with his management
team and hired consultants to devise strategies to help the market
view the Company as "a sum of the parts." Mr. Dell regularly
communicated his views to analysts. |
Unsurprisingly this didn't work. So he
made the argument in a more persuasive way: In 2012, with the market
not getting Dell and valuing it at just $9.35 a share, he rounded up
some financing sources and offered to pay about $12 or so for it.[4]
That argument worked, eventually. Michael Dell and his private-equity
backers at Silver Lake ended up paying about $13.75 a share ($13.96
counting some dividends) in a $25 billion deal that they signed in
February 2013 and closed in October of that year.[5]
There were twists and turns along the way; in particular, Carl Icahn
held up the deal for a while by arguing that Dell was actually worth
much more than $13.75 a share. But Icahn's arguments were not
ultimately persuasive, because they consisted mostly of words and
numbers and not money. (They were somewhat persuasive because they
involved some money -- Icahn made a couple of leveraged
recapitalization proposals for Dell that would pay some cash to
shareholders that might have sort of looked like a higher price than
$13.75 -- but that isn't quite the same as bidding $14 a share for all
the shares in ready cash.)
And then some shareholders sued in an
appraisal lawsuit, arguing that the $13.75 was too low and that a
Delaware court should award them more money. And then most of those
shareholders were thrown out of court for hilarious legalistic reasons
that don't concern us here, though they have
concerned us
previously.[6]
But on Tuesday Delaware Vice Chancellor Travis Laster ruled on the
remaining appraisal claims and found, in a
114-page opinion, that Dell
was really worth $17.62 a share, so everyone who successfully sued --
and managed to jump through the correct hoops -- is entitled to an
extra $3.87 a share, with interest.[7]
Appraisal is a
weird bit of corporate law, because it undermines the usual nice clean
process of deciding how much a stock is worth by just seeing what
someone will pay for it. The market said Dell was worth $9.35, or
whatever, and Silver Lake said it was worth $13.75 and paid that, and
then some shareholders said it was worth even more. The normal form of
financial-markets argumentation would be for them to offer more. But
instead they get to sue, and make arguments to the court, and then
Michael Dell and Silver Lake have to make arguments about why it's
worth less. Their heart is unlikely to be in those arguments
since, you know, they paid the $13.75, which implies that they think
it's worth more than that. But their best argument will always be: If
this company was worth more than $13.75 a share, why did no one offer
more?
And that is a
pretty good argument! The best reply, especially in a conflicted
management buyout where the buyer is also the CEO, is often along the
lines of "because management deliberately undermined the sales process
to prevent other bidders from seeing the company's true value, so they
could take it for themselves on the cheap." But that's not really what
happened here; the court found that, while there were some inherent
conflicts of interest, Dell's independent directors basically did a
bang-up job of running the sales process,[8]
and even Michael Dell himself -- despite being both the CEO and the
prospective buyer of the company -- behaved like a prince.[9]
Actually, reading the opinion, you almost get the sense that Michael
Dell didn't do this leveraged buyout for the money. It was just an
intellectual engagement, a point of principle. He thought the
stock was undervalued, and he wanted to argue his case, and the way
you argue that is by buying all the stock.
But the court
nonetheless disagreed with the price, and decided that the fair price
was $17.62. To get there, first of all, Vice Chancellor Laster had to
disregard the market price for the stock, which was $9.35 when the
deal was first proposed, $13.42 when it was
officially signed, and never
closed above $14.51 afterward.[10] These
lower prices are not too hard to explain away:
A second
factor that undermined the persuasiveness of the Original Merger
Consideration as evidence of fair value was the widespread and
compelling evidence of a valuation gap between the market‘s
perception and the Company‘s operative reality. The gap was driven
by (i) analysts' focus on short-term, quarter-by-quarter results
and (ii) the Company‘s nearly $14 billion investment in its
transformation, which had not yet begun to generate the
anticipated results. A transaction which eliminates stockholders
may take advantage of a trough in a company‘s performance or
excessive investor pessimism about the Company's prospects (a
so-called anti-bubble). Indeed, the optimal time to take a company
private is after it has made significant long-term investments,
but before those investments have started to pay off and market
participants have begun to incorporate those benefits into the
price of the Company‘s stock. |
That is: The market price didn't reflect
fair value, not because the market didn't have the relevant
information, but because it weighted it incorrectly. Analysts had a
myopic "focus on short-term, quarter-by-quarter results," and couldn't
understand the long-term value of the company's plan. This is true
even though Dell's management explained its long-term plan and "tried
to convince the market that the Company was worth more." The stock
market, in Vice Chancellor Laster's view, was just incorrigibly short-termist,
and couldn't take the long view and value Dell properly.[11]
After all,
that's why Michael Dell wanted to take the company private in the
first place:
Mr. Dell
identified the opportunity to take the Company private after the
stock market failed to reflect the Company‘s going concern value
over a prolonged period. He managed the Company for the long-term
and understood that his strategic decisions would drive the stock
price down in the short-term. |
So he went to
private-equity firms to fix his short-termism problem. This makes
sense! If you have a public market that doesn't properly value a
company because it is too short-term focused, you can ask a
private-equity firm to buy the company and run it for the long term,
without the pressure of quarterly earnings calls and microsecond
stock-price moves. That was Michael Dell's thinking, and Silver
Lake's, and it's a pretty standard move. And the next standard move
would be to have an auction among private-equity firms to figure out
how much they think the company is worth. That more or less
happened here; the auction was imperfect, but ultimately three
private-equity firms put a lot of effort into Dell, with KKR and
Blackstone putting in bids at various points before dropping out of
the running.[12]
The highest price that private equity was willing to pay for Dell was
$13.75, give or take, significantly above the pre-announcement market
price.
Meanwhile no
strategic buyer -- no other company that might want to acquire
Dell's business -- put in a bid.[13] So
the best bid that anyone with a long-term perspective put in was
$13.75.
So why wasn't that the right
price?[14] The
opinion on this is interesting, and it turns on the difference between
an "LBO model" and a "DCF model." Here is the oversimplified
difference:[15]
1. A discounted
cash flow model
makes some assumptions about the company's future cash flows, assumes
a reasonable capital structure, discounts those cash flows back to the
present based on the company's cost of debt and a market-based cost of
equity capital, and comes up with a value per share reflecting the
present value of those cash flows.
2. A
leveraged buyout model does
the same thing, except that the capital structure is more leveraged
and, instead of a reasonable cost of equity capital, it assumes a 20
percent to 30 percent cost of equity capital.
Again, this is super oversimplified;
please don't use this description to prepare for your investment
banking interviews. But the basic idea is: Private-equity firms like
to buy companies for less than they're worth, so that they can make
20-plus percent returns on their equity investments, so that their own
investors will be happy with them and pay them their big fees. Public
investors are satisfied with market-rate returns. Vice Chancellor
Laster's DCF calculation used an 11.3 percent expected return for
Dell's equity.[16]
If you expect an 11.3 percent return, you will be willing to pay more
for a company than you will if you expect a 30 percent return. That is
just math.[17]
So you see the
problem. Private-equity firms will only buy companies for cheap and
lever them up, so they can get the 20-plus percent returns that their
investors demand. So any price that a private-equity firm will
pay for a public company is inherently suspect, since private-equity
firms expect such high returns. So Vice Chancellor Laster ignored the
price that Silver Lake actually paid, after a quasi-auction among
private-equity firms. He chose his own DCF model, with lower expected
returns, and calculated a higher price for Dell.[18]
And then he declared that that was the fair value.
I realize
that this all sounds pretty naive when I put it like that, but it is
kind of ... exactly what Vice Chancellor Laster says? This paragraph,
near the end of the opinion, is deeply weird:
The fair
value generated by the DCF methodology comports with the evidence
regarding the outcome of the sale process. The sale process
functioned imperfectly as a price discovery tool, both during the
pre-signing and post-signing phases. Its structure and result are
sufficiently credible to exclude an outlier valuation for the
Company like the one the petitioners advanced, but sufficient
pricing anomalies and dis-incentives to bid existed to create the
possibility that the sale process permitted an undervaluation of
several dollars per share. Financial sponsors using an LBO model
could not have bid close to $18 per share because of their IRR
requirements and the Company's inability to support the necessary
levels of leverage. Assuming the $17.62 figure is right, then a
strategic acquirer that perceived the Company‘s value could have
gotten the Company for what was approximately a 25% discount.
Given the massive integration risk inherent in such a deal, it is
not entirely surprising that HP did not engage and that no one
else came forward. |
That is, Vice
Chancellor Laster checked his work -- and his price of $17.62 -- by
looking at the actual results of Dell's sales process, which got a
price of $13.75. If Dell was worth $17.62, then no strategic buyer
would be willing to bid more than $13.75, because at only a 25 percent
discount to fair value "the massive integration risk" would make Dell
unappetizing. And if Dell was worth $17.62, then no private-equity
buyers would be willing to bid more than $13.75, "because of their IRR
requirements and the Company‘s inability to support the necessary
levels of leverage."[19] The
proof that $17.62 was the fair price is that no one was willing to
pay it:
1. Public
shareholders won't pay fair value for Dell, because they are obsessed
with the short term and can't understand the long-term strategic
vision.
2. No strategic
buyer would pay fair value to buy Dell, because that would be risky.
3. No
private-equity buyer would pay fair value to buy Dell, because
private-equity firms only buy companies at a discount.[20]
So how could any
merger deliver fair value to shareholders? This opinion creates its
own weird valuation gap. Public-equity markets, let us assume, focus
too much on the short term, and undervalue companies whose immediate
results don't match their long-term prospects. The solution to that
short-term-ism might be to go private so you can focus on the long
term. But private-equity firms undervalue companies because, let us
also assume, they demand an above-market rate of return and so will
only buy companies at a discount. The only buyer willing to pay fair
price for a company, apparently, would be a buyer with the relatively
long-term focus of private-equity firms and the relatively low-return
expectations of public-equity investors. Perhaps such a buyer exists.
But it would be a little weird. After all, the higher returns are the
compensation private equity gets for taking the longer view (and
longer-term risks). And ample short-term liquidity is what
allows public markets to afford the lower-return expectations.
Why should there
be mergers? Sometimes there are synergies: Company A and Company B
will be better off together, because they can sell each others'
products or cut back-office costs or whatever. Sometimes there are
governance benefits: Company A's current managers don't know what
they're doing, and an acquirer could install better managers with
better ideas that make it worth more money. Either way, the merger
creates value by making the business better. That's not what happened
in Dell:
This was not
a case in which the Buyout Group intended to make changes in the
Company‘s business, either organically or through acquisitions.
The Buyout Group intended to achieve its returns simply by
executing the Company‘s existing business strategy and meeting its
forecasted projections. Mr. Dell identified for the Committee the
strategies that he would pursue once the Company was private, and
the record establishes that all of them could have been
accomplished in a public company setting. BCG recognized and
advised the Committee that the only benefits Mr. Dell could
realize by taking the Company private that were not otherwise
available as a public company were (i) accessing offshore cash
with less tax leakage (to pay down the acquisition debt) and (ii)
arbitraging the value of the Company itself by buying low and
selling high. |
I suppose that
sounds derogatory, but there are those who think that "arbitraging the
value of the company itself by buying low and selling high" is ... I
don't want to say a noble purpose, but let's say, the most noble
possible purpose. When Michael Dell proposed a buyout, the company's
price was wrong. Everyone involved in this case agrees on that.
Michael Dell thought -- and said -- that Dell was undervalued. The
Dell board said that it was undervalued. Its financial advisers said
it was undervalued. Silver Lake thought it was undervalued. When the
deal was announced, Carl Icahn said it was undervalued. When the deal
closed, the appraisal plaintiffs sued, saying it was undervalued. And
now a judge has decided it was undervalued.
But Michael Dell
and Silver Lake are the ones who did something about it.
Everyone says Dell's market price was too low; they skipped the
talk and just offered to pay more. This buyout didn't create value by
changing Dell's business model; it created value by changing Dell's
ownership -- by moving the shares from people who mostly didn't value
them that highly (public markets) to people who did (private-equity
buyers). It didn't create synergies or improve Dell's sales, sure, but
it did correct an error. There are those who would say that's a
worthwhile thing to do. The court, though, suggests that it isn't.
1.
I kid, I kid. It is called "economics."
2.
In principle there is no reason to think
that "public markets are too focused on short-term results" would
imply "public markets undervalue
companies." Of course many companies are performing better now than
they will in five years, and a short-term-oriented market will overvalue those
companies. But you more usually hear arguments that imply that markets
undervalue, like, research and development or whatever, than arguments
that imply that markets overvalue, like, making money today, though
there are exceptions.
3.
This is from Tuesday's appraisal
opinion. Citations omitted, here and throughout.
4.
Here I simplify a long and complicated
process. Michael Dell was first approached about a management
buyout in June 2012, and first raised it with
the board in August. He worked with KKR and Silver Lake on their
proposals, which they first submitted in October 2012. From the
appraisal opinion:
|
Silver Lake proposed an all-cash transaction valued at between
$11.22 and $12.16 a share, excluding shares held by Mr. Dell. KKR
proposed an all-cash transaction valued at between $12.00 and
$13.00 a share, excluding shares held by Mr. Dell and
Southeastern, and based its illustrative analysis on a price of
$12.50 per share. KKR‘s proposal also contemplated an additional
$500 million investment by Mr. Dell. Dell‘s common stock closed at
$9.35 that day. |
|
There were many further revisions. And it's not quite right to say
that Michael Dell offered the $12:
|
Mr. Dell had not been involved in determining the prices. He was
content to participate at whatever pricing the financial sponsors
obtained. |
|
5.
The merger consideration was $13.75 a
share, plus a special dividend of $0.13 a share, plus a regular
third-quarter dividend of $0.08 a share,
regardless of when the deal closed. (See pages 36-37 of the appraisal
opinion.) In the rest of this post I'm going to use $13.75 because I
assume that that's the relevant comparison for appraisal purposes.
That is, if you sought appraisal and turned down the merger
consideration, you still got the 21 cents worth of dividends, so the
fair comparison is between the appraisal price and the $13.75 deal
price.
6.
The big loser was
T. Rowe Price:
|
Tuesday’s ruling could have been far costlier for Mr. Dell and
Silver Lake. Earlier this month, a judge disqualified about 30
million shares held by T. Rowe Price Group Inc. because the mutual
fund giant, one of the deal’s most vocal opponents, mistakenly
voted its shares in favor of the buyout. To be eligible for the
court-ordered price bump, investors must have voted against the
transaction.
The mix-up, which T. Rowe has blamed on the complexities of the
proxy voting system, means it will miss out on about $190 million,
including interest. |
|
Oops!
7.
I mean, he decided they were entitled to
$17.62 a share, with interest on the whole amount. It's a lot of
interest really. In any case, though,
there weren't that many of them:
|
But the ruling likely won’t cost Mr. Dell and Silver Lake much
because only a tiny fraction of shares are eligible for the bump,
because of quirks in Delaware law. The largest holder is hedge
fund Magnetar Capital, which has rights to about 3.8 million
shares and stands to collect about $15 million. |
|
8.
Page 61 of the opinion:
|
In this case, the Company‘s process easily would sail through if
reviewed under enhanced scrutiny. The Committee and its advisors
did many praiseworthy things, and it would burden an already long
opinion to catalog them. In a liability proceeding, this court
could not hold that the directors breached their fiduciary duties
or that there could be any basis for liability.
|
|
9.
I really can't get over how he didn't have
a say on the price in the private equity firms' initial bids, and
"was content to participate at
whatever pricing the financial sponsors obtained." He worked in
parallel with both Silver Lake and KKR, and then later when Blackstone
was kicking the tires he spent a lot of time with them too -- even
though they mused publicly about getting rid of him if they bought the
company. And to help Silver Lake get its bid up, he was willing to
roll over his shares at a lower valuation. He just doesn't seem to
have done any underhanded nickel-and-dime-y stuff; you get the sense
that if someone was willing to pay more he would have tried to make it
work.
10.
The fact that it closed above the deal
price does, of course, suggest that some people thought that it was
worth more than that deal price.
(And/or that Carl Icahn, or someone, would get them a better deal.)
11.
By the way, I am not sure this is exactly
fair to the public analysts. Here, from page 33, is a description of
the reaction to May 2013 earnings:
|
"Most [analysts] were shocked at the profitability results."
Revenues beat Street estimates by about 4%, but earnings per share
came in approximately 29% below the consensus. According to BCG,
the quarter "miss [was] HUGE." Analysts disagreed about the
long-term implications for the Company. The Bernstein analyst
focused on the enterprise solutions and services division, noting
that it generated "essentially no profits," which was "a sober
finding, given the company‘s strategic intent is to migrate the
company to enterprise offerings." The analyst attributed the
division‘s poor performance to "myriad factors – none of which
have easy fixes.". |
|
This isn't dumb short-termism. It's using presently available data --
the only available data -- to try to predict Dell's long-term
prospects. What else were the analysts supposed to do?
12.
Amusingly, Vice Chancellor Laster writes
that "KKR‘s investment committee had concluded that the
Company‘s recent operating performance validated
analysts‘ concerns." That is: KKR, a long-term private-equity
investor, concluded that the public analysts might have been on to
something. It wasn't alone: The special committee of independent
directors also approached TPG, which "reported to the Committee that
it believed the 'cash flows attached to the PC business were simply
too uncertain, too unpredictable to establish an investment case.'"
13.
After the deal was signed, Dell's bankers
at Evercore ran a "go-shop" process where they tried to find a
higher bidder. They were hopeful for
Hewlett-Packard, the obvious strategic buyer, but while HP signed a
confidentiality agreement, it "never accessed the data room and did
not submit an indication of interest." On the other hand:
|
On March 21, 2013, GE Capital submitted a bid to acquire the
Company‘s financial services unit for $3.6 billion in cash. GE
Capital said it was happy to have the Committee consider its offer
in connection with any other bid.
|
|
That never seems to have gone anywhere.
14.
The opinion has some interesting general
statements about why courts shouldn't be too deferential to the
market. Pages 47-48:
|
Recent jurisprudence has emphasized Delaware courts‘ willingness
to consider market price data generated not only by the market for
individual shares but also by the market for the company as a
whole. If the merger giving rise to appraisal rights "resulted
from an arm‘s-length process between two independent parties, and
if no structural impediments existed that might materially distort
the 'crucible of objective market reality,'" then "a reviewing
court should give substantial evidentiary weight to the merger
price as an indicator of fair value."
Here too, however, the Delaware Supreme Court has eschewed market
fundamentalism by making clear that market price data is neither
conclusively determinative of nor presumptively equivalent to fair
value. |
|
And pages 52-53:
|
Writing as a Vice Chancellor, Chief Justice Strine observed that
even for purposes of determining the value of individual shares,
where the stock market is typically thick and liquid, the
proponents of the efficient capital markets hypothesis no longer
make the strong-form claim that the market price actually
determines fundamental value; at most they make the semi-strong
claim that market prices reflect all available information and are
efficient at incorporating new information. The M&A market has
fewer buyers and one seller, and the dissemination of critical,
non-public due diligence information is limited to participants
who sign confidentiality agreements. It is therefore erroneous to
"conflate the stock market (which is generally highly efficient)
with the deal market (which often is not)." It is perhaps more
erroneous to claim that the thinner M&A market generates a price
consistent with fundamental efficiency, when the same claim is no
longer made for the thicker markets in individual shares.
|
|
On the other hand, there are limits. Pages 83-84:
|
Based on this evidence, the Company makes a straightforward
argument: Capitalists want to make money, and America is full of
capitalists, so it is counterintuitive and illogical—to the point
of being incredible—to think that another party would not have
topped Mr. Dell and Silver Lake if the Company was actually worth
more. In my view, this argument has force for large valuation
gaps, and is sufficiently persuasive to negate the valuation of
$28.61 per share that the petitioners advanced. If the Company was
really worth more than double what the Buyout Group was paying,
then a strategic bidder like HP would have recognized a compelling
opportunity and intervened.
|
|
15.
Here is the footnote acknowledging that
there are other differences. Also the LBO model is usually
expressed as solving for a 20-30 percent internal
rate of return hurdle rather than using a 20-30 percent cost of equity
capital and solving for a price. Here's how the opinion puts it (page
63):
|
When proposing an MBO, a financial sponsor determines whether and
how much to bid by using an LBO model, which solves for the range
of prices that a financial sponsor can pay while still achieving
particular IRRs. What the sponsor is willing to pay diverges from
fair value because of (i) the financial sponsor‘s need to achieve
IRRs of 20% or more to satisfy its own investors and (ii) limits
on the amount of leverage that the company can support and the
sponsor can use to finance the deal. Although a DCF methodology
and an LBO model use similar inputs, they solve for different
variables: "[T]he DCF analysis solves for the present value of the
firm, while the LBO model solves for the internal rate of return." |
|
16.
See pages 107-109 of the opinion,
calculating the weighted average cost of capital:
1.
He assumes a capital structure of 75
percent equity, 25 percent debt.
2.
The cost of debt is 4.95 percent, with a
tax rate of 21 percent (see pages 105-107), for an after-tax cost of
3.91 percent.
3.
The risk-free rate is 3.31 percent, the
beta is 1.31, and the market equity risk premium is 6.11 percent, for
a cost of equity of 11.31 percent.
4.
The weighted average cost of capital is
thus 9.46 percent.
17.
I mean, it cheats a bit on the math, in
that the LBO model uses a lot more leverage than Vice Chancellor
Laster's 75-percent-equity DCF model,
and with that much leverage the capital-asset-pricing-model cost of
equity would be much higher.
18.
By the way, DCF models aren't perfect
either. Page 90:
|
The petitioners‘ expert, Professor Bradford Cornell, used a DCF
analysis to opine that the Company had a fair value of $28.61 per
share on the closing date. The respondent‘s expert, Professor
Glenn Hubbard, used a DCF analysis to opine that the Company had a
fair value of $12.68 per share on the closing date. Two highly
distinguished scholars of valuation science, applying similar
valuation principles, thus generated opinions that differed by
126%, or approximately $28 billion.
|
|
Meh, whatever.
19.
The opinion is full of stuff like this.
Page 86: The fact that Blackstone and Icahn emerged during the go-shop
period "indicates that the Original Merger Consideration was low not
only when judged against a fair value metric, but also when judged by
an LBO model." That is: An LBO model
intrinsically undervalues a company.
To be fair Vice Chancellor Laster has some support for this view in
this case. Page 65:
|
Using the same set of projections for both a DCF analysis and an
LBO analysis, JPMorgan showed why a financial sponsor would not be
willing to pay an amount approaching the Company‘s going-concern
value. Using the September Case and a DCF analysis, JPMorgan
valued the Company as a going concern at between $20 and $27 per
share. But using the same projected cash flows in an LBO model,
JPMorgan projected that a financial buyer‘s willingness to pay
would max out at approximately $14.13 per share, because at higher
prices, the sponsor could not achieve a minimum return hurdle of a
20% IRR over five years. That $14.13 figure also assumed the
sponsor engaged in further recapitalizations of the Company.
Assuming a financial sponsor wanted to achieve IRRs in the range
of 20% to 25%, JPMorgan placed the likely range of prices at
$11.75 to $13.00, or $13.25 to $14.25 if the sponsor engaged in
further recapitalizations of the Company.
|
|
20.
Because they have high IRR hurdles.
Because buying companies in leveraged buyouts is risky!
This column does not necessarily reflect the opinion of the editorial
board or Bloomberg LP and its owners.
To contact the author of this story:
Matt Levine at
mlevine51@bloomberg.net
To contact the editor responsible for this story:
James Greiff at
jgreiff@bloomberg.net
©2016 Bloomberg L.P. All Rights Reserved |